As an Amazon Associate I earn from qualifying purchases #ad

brainroads-toward-tomorrows mental patterns

pyramid2dna

pyramid to dna

Landmarks of Tomorrow

(1957 - 1959)

by Peter Drucker

Amazon link: Landmarks of tomorrow

 

 

Landmarks table of contents

 

 

 

line

 

#Note the number of books about Drucker ↓

books-about-drucker-collage-pict-t-600

Inside Drucker's Brain World According to Drucker

My life as a knowledge worker

Drucker: a political or social ecologist ↑ ↓

 

“I am not a ‘theoretician’;

through my consulting practice

I am in daily touch with

the concrete opportunities and problems

of a fairly large number of institutions,

foremost among them businesses

but also hospitals, government agencies

and public-service institutions

such as museums and universities.

 

And I am working with such institutions

on several continents:

North America, including Canada and Mexico;

Latin America; Europe;

Japan and South East Asia.

 

Still, a consultant is at one remove

from the day-today practice —

that is both his strength

and his weakness.

And so my viewpoint

tends more to be that of an outsider.”

broad worldview ↑ ↓

 

Most mistakes in thinking ↑seeing only part of the picture

peter-drucker-timescape_600x545

#pdw larger ↑ ::: Books by Peter Drucker ::: Rick Warren + Drucker

Peter Drucker's work

Books by Bob Buford and Walter Wriston

Global Peter Drucker Forum ::: Charles Handy — Starting small fires

Post-capitalist executive ↑ T. George Harris

evidence-wall-and-time-line-pict-600

harvest and implement

Learning to Learn (ecological awareness ::: operacy)

The MEMO “they” don’t want you to SEE

 

line

 

 

Also see about management

 

 

Landmarks — Table of Contents

 

 

Introduction: This Post-Modern World

 

At some unmarked point during the last twenty years we imperceptibly moved out of the Modern Age and into a new, as yet nameless, era.

 

Post-CAPITALIST Society

 

The New Pluralism (1957)

 

Moving Beyond CAPITALISM

 

Our view of the world changed; we acquired a new perception and with it new capacities.

There are new frontiers of opportunity, risk and challenge.

There is a new spiritual center to human existence.  


 

The old view of the world, the old tasks and the old center, calling themselves “modern” and “up to date” only a few years ago, just make no sense any more.

They still provide our rhetoric, whether of politics or of science, at home or in foreign affairs.

But the slogans and battle cries of all parties, be they political, philosophical, aesthetic or scientific, no longer serve to unite for action—though they still can divide in heat and emotion.

Our actions are already measured against the stern demands of thetoday,” the “post-modern world”; and yet we have no theories, no concepts, no slogans—no real knowledge—about the new reality.  


finding and selecting the pieces of the puzzle

 

Indeed anyone over forty lives in a different world from that in which he came to manhood, lives as if he had emigrated, fully grown, to a new and strange country.

For three hundred years, from the middle of the seventeenth century on, the West lived in the Modern Age; and during the last century this modern West became the norm of philosophy and politics, society, science and economy all over the globe, became the first truly universal world order.

Today it is no longer living reality—but the new world, though real, if not indeed obvious to us, is not yet established.  


We thus live in an age of transition, an age of overlap, in which the old “modern” of yesterday no longer acts effectively but still provides means of expression, standards of expectations and tools of ordering, while the new, the “post-modern,” still lacks definition, expression and tools but effectively controls our actions and their impact.  


This book is a report on the new post-modern today we live in—nothing more.

It does not deal with the future.

It deals with the tangible present.

Indeed I have tried to resist the temptation to speculate about what might be, let alone to predict what will be.

I have not even tried to pull together into one order of values and perceptions what are still individual pieces.

radar_limited-pict-no-reflect-400

↑ finding and selecting the pieces of the puzzle

 

Till this is done, we shall not, of course, have a really new age with its own distinct character and worldview; we shall only be “post” something else.  


As I saw the job, it was to understand rather than to innovate, to describe rather than to imagine.

This is, of course, by far the smaller and less important of the tasks to be done; we still need the great imaginer, the great creative thinker, the great innovator, of a new synthesis, of a new philosophy and of new institutions.  


This book encompasses a very wide horizon; yet it is incomplete.

Essentially I have tried to cover three big areas, each representing a major dimension of human life and experience:  


The new view of the world, the new concepts, the new human capacities:

The first part of the book (Chapters One, Two and Three) treats the philosophical shift from the Cartesian universe of mechanical cause to the new universe of pattern, purpose and process.

I have also explored our new power purposefully to innovate, both technologically and socially, and the resulting emergence of new opportunity, new risk and new responsibility.

There is a discussion of the new power to organize men of knowledge and high skill for joint effort and performance through the exercise of responsible judgment, which has given us both the new and central institution of the large organization and a new ideal of social order in which society and individual become mutually dependent poles of human freedom and achievement.

The new frontiers, the new tasks and opportunities:

The second part (Chapters Four through Nine) sketches four new realities, each of them a challenge, above all to the peoples of the Free World.

The first is the emergence of Educated Society—a society in which only the educated man is truly productive, in which increasingly everybody will, at least in respect to years spent in school, have received a higher education, and in which the educational status of a country becomes a controlling factor in international competition and survival.

What does this mean for society and the individual?

What does it mean for education?

The second is the emergence of Economic Development—“Up to Poverty”—as the new, common vision and goal of humanity, and of international and interracial class war as the new threat.

Third is the decline of the government of the nation-state, the “modern government” of yesteryear, its increasing inability to govern internally and to act internationally.

And fourth is the new reality of the collapse of theEast,” that is of non-Western culture and civilization, to the point where no viable society anywhere can be built except upon Western formulations.  


A short concluding section—only a few paragraphs—asks:

What does all this mean for the nations of the West and for the direction, goals and principles of their government and policies?

The human situation:

The third and last part (Chapter Ten) is concerned with the new spiritual—or, if one prefers the word, metaphysical—reality of human existence: the fact that both knowledge and power have become absolute, have gained the capacity for absolute destruction beyond which no refinement, no increase is meaningful any more.

This, for the first time since the dawn of our civilization, forces us to think through the nature, function and control of both.

 

Though I have tried to be faithful to the facts I am certain that I have often misunderstood themas any newcomer to a strange country is bound to misunderstand.

Though I have tried to be objective I am conscious of my Western background, and of my bias—that of the great tradition of European and especially Anglo-American conservatism with its beliefs in liberty, law and justice, in responsibility and work, in the uniqueness of the person and the fallibility of the creature.

I am equally conscious of the limitations of my knowledge and understanding—above all of my weaknesses in the creative arts.

But, still, I hope that the aim of this book: to report and to give understanding, has been reached at least to the point where it conveys to the reader both the shock of recognition—how obvious the unfamiliar new already is; and the shock of estrangement—how irrelevant the familiar modern of yesterday has already become.

 

 

Introduction To The Transaction Edition

This book was called "futuristic" when it first appeared.

But I do not believe in "forecasting"or in "predicting"; I consider them futile and self-defeating.

This book should properly be considered an "early diagnosis."

It looks at the society of the late 1950s, and especially at American society, and asks: 

Where have major changes already happened that will make the future very different from what most of us still assume to be "normal," from what most of us still take for granted?

In fact, my first title was The Future that has Already Happened — and dropped it only because it was too long to fit comfortably on a title page.


But the book did start out with the assumption that there had been a drastic change and that we had already moved out of one era, hence the book's subtitle, A Report on the New Post-Modern World.

And the word "post-modern" was to the best of my knowledge first used in this book, was indeed coined by me.

The book then went on to ask: 

In what areas have these changes occurred?

Which ones are of major importance?

What does each of them imply and mean?

What do we have to learn, to unlearn, to do as a result of these developments?


In many ways this book represents a major departure from my earlier work.


Eight years earlier I had published the last of three books analyzing and presenting the new industrial society that had emerged out of World War II, 

The Future of Industrial Man (1942); 

Concept of the Corporation (1946); and 

The New Society (1949) 

— all of which have since been reissued by Transaction.

In the meantime I had begun work on the study of the constitutive institution of that society, management, and had, in 1954, published the first — and most fundamental — of my books on the subject, 

The Practice of Management, followed in later years by Managing for Results (1964), the first book on what we now call "strategy"; 

The Effective Executive (1966), the first book on what we now call "leadership"; 

Management Tasks, Responsibility Practices (1973), an attempt to pull together in one definitive volume all we know about management, both as a specific work and as a major social function; 

Innovation and Entrepreneurship (1986), the first presentation of entrepreneurship as a systematic discipline and of innovation as organized, systematic, purposeful work; 

and finally in 1991, Managing the Non-Profit Organization, the first attempt to project management, leadership, and entrepreneurship on the non-profit sector of society and its institutions.

Landmarks of Tomorrow was thus different both from my earlier work in social analysis and from the books that over the next thirty years became the best known works of mine: 

the books on management, not "business" management but management as specific work, specific discipline, specific responsibility, specific social functions.

Landmarks of Tomorrow did, however, set the format and approach followed since by all my later books on society: 

The Age of Discontinuity (1969), 

The Unseen Revolution (1976; both of which have also been reissued by Transaction), 

The New Realities (1989/90), and 

Post Capitalist Society (1993).

They are all books dealing with basic changes in the foundations of society, all books that try to do what Landmarks of Tomorrow first tried to, that is, to present the future that has already happened.


Now, thirty-five years later, it is proper to ask whether events have since borne out this early diagnosis?

On the whole, they have.

The main findings of this book were 

the shift from nineteenth-century automatic progress to systematic, purposeful, organized innovation; 

the shift to knowledge as the new major resource; 

the emergence of a pluralistic society of organizations; 

the crisis in the effectiveness of modern government — rather amazing in that this finding was made just a few years before the Kennedy presidency seemed to enthrone government as the new "Enlightened, and All-Powerful Despot"; 

and finally the shift to a global economy and, indeed, a global society.

Only one of the major findings has not been validated by events since or rather only in part.

And yet, it was the finding that evoked the most comment and interest when the book was first published: 

the finding that a new worldview, a new holistic philosophy was rapidly emerging.

This finding that we were moving, and fast, from a Cartesian view of the world as a mechanical aggregate in which the whole is the sum of its parts to a worldview of configurations or Gestalten in which the whole is different from its parts has indeed happened in the disciplines that, in the last thirty-five years, have progressed the most: 

in biogenetics, biophysics and molecular biology; 

in psychology with its new focus on "personality"; 

in meteorology and in the earth sciences; 

in the emergence of "ecology"; 

in mathematics with chaos theory and the mathematics of complexity.

But it has not happened in philosophy itself.


There we have been moving to even more extreme Cartesian atomism in which there is no whole at all but only parts: in philosophical linguistics and in deconstructivism.

There is an old saying that philosophy follows the dominant scientific world paradigm and transforms it into "worldview" and metaphysics — the best example is Immanuel Kant following Isaac Newton.

But Kant followed Newton a good fifty years later.

(Newton died in 1727 and Kant, born in 1724, did not publish a major work (The Critique of Pure Reason] until 1781).

If that is the pattern, we should expect the new philosophy to be born around the year 2000 that is, more than forty years after I had prematurely announced its arrival!


But worse than being premature in a diagnosis is to miss and overlook a major development.

And Landmarks of Tomorrow missed the information revolution.


This is all the stranger as the author, in those years, worked closely with IBM, one of the leading computer manufacturers, lectured to its managers, and altogether preached to all that the computer was not just a gadget but represented a veritable revolution in the way we were going to do work, be organized, think, and that, indeed, the computer was but a symptom of a basic change the change from experience to information.

Indeed I gained a reputation as somewhat of a bore on this subject and yet inexplicably there is not a word on information to be found in Landmarks of Tomorrow; that had to wait until my next book of social analysis, the 1969 Age of Discontinuity.

If the book were to be given a score as an "early diagnosis" it would thus not get an "A+."

But it probably deserves an "A-"; in its main thesis — that here had been a shift — and in identifying the main new developments, it was on target.


There is one feature of the book, however, that will surprise today's reader — it surprised me when I reread the book to write this introduction: the book's optimism.

It deals with weighty issues and major challenges, but it is a confident book — whether in respect to economic development (where it correctly saw the coming emergence of Japan as a developed and powerful economy), in respect to political structure and organization, or in respect to knowledge and education.

It does not minimize the problems and challenges.

But it looks at them as work to be done — the title of the penultimate chapter — rather than as burdens or crises.


Six years after the book was published, with President Kennedy's assassination, we then entered the long period of agony, crises, despair, and horrors — and not only in American society.

Perhaps it is not too optimistic to look upon this long period as a time of transition to the emergence of the "post-modern" world on which this book first reported, and on all the horrors and crises of these thirty five years as turbulences of that transition.

Perhaps it is not too optimistic to hope that the period now ahead, after this reissue of Landmarks of Tomorrow, will justify the optimism with which the book was written more than thirty-five years ago.


PETER F. DRUCKER

Claremont, California

November 1995

 

line

 

Basic contents (expanded contents follow)

 

 

line

 

Expanded contents

Introduction: This Post-Modern World

Introduction To The Transaction Edition

The New World-View

In the fall of 1956 two brothers—intelligent, well-educated, graduate students in their twenties—went to see a play on the New York stage, Inherit the Wind.

This was a dramatization of the notorious Scopes “Monkey” trial of 1925 in which a schoolteacher in rural Tennessee was convicted for teaching Darwin’s Theory of Evolution, and in which the great nineteenth-century conflict between science and religion reached a climax of total absurdity.

When the brothers came home they said they were much impressed by the acting but rather baffled by the plot.

What, they wanted to know, was all the excitement about?

Their father, when their age, had been so deeply stirred by the trial that he had given up the ministry and become a lawyer.

But when he tried to explain its meaning and its excitement to his sons they both exclaimed, “You are making this up.

Why, it makes no sense at all.”  


The point of this story is that one of the sons is a graduate geneticist, the other one a theological student in a Presbyterian and strictly Calvinist seminary.

Yet the “conflict between science and religion” could not even be explained to either of them.  


It is almost frightening how fast the obvious of yesteryear is turning incomprehensible.

An intelligent and well-educated man of the first modern generation—that of Newton, Hobbes and Locke—might still have been able to understand and to make himself understood up to World War II.

But it is unlikely that he could still communicate with the world of today, only fifteen years later.

We ourselves, after all, saw in the last election campaign how rapidly the issues, slogans, concerns and alignments of as recent a period as the thirties have become irrelevant, if not actually incomprehensible.  


But what matters most for us—the first post-modern generation—is the change in fundamental world-view.  


We still profess and we still teach the world-view of the past three hundred years.

But we no longer see it.

We have as yet no name for our new vision, no tools, no method and no vocabulary.

But a world-view is, above all, an experience.

It is the foundation of artistic perception, philosophical analysis and technical vocabulary.

And we have acquired this new foundation, all of a sudden, within these last fifteen or twenty years.

bbx “The Whole Is the Sum of Its Parts”

But Descartes’ formulation also implied that the whole is determined by the parts, and that, therefore, we can know the whole only by identifying and knowing the parts.

It implied that the behavior of the whole is caused by the motion of the parts.

It implied above all that there is no “whole” altogether as apart from the different sums, structures and relationships of parts.  


These statements are likely to sound obvious today; they have been taken for granted for three hundred years—even though they were the most radical innovations when first propounded.  


But though most of us still have the conditioned reflex of familiarity toward these assertions, there are few scientists today who would still accept the definition of the Académie Française—at least not for what they call “science” in their own field.

Every one of our disciplines, sciences and arts today bases itself on concepts which are incompatible with the Cartesian axiom and with the world-view of the modern West developed therefrom.

bbx From Cause to Configuration

Every one of our disciplines has moved from cause to configuration.  


Every discipline has as its center today a concept of a whole that is not the result of its parts, not equal to the sum of its parts, and not identifiable, knowable, measurable, predictable, effective or meaningful through identifying, knowing, measuring, predicting, moving or understanding the parts.

The central concepts in every one of our modern disciplines, sciences and arts are patterns and configurations.  


Biology shows this more dramatically perhaps than any other science.

The tremendous development of biology in the last fifty years is the result of the application of strict Cartesian method—the methods of classical mechanics, of analytical chemistry or of mathematical statistics—to the study of the living organism.

But the more “scientific” the biologist has become, the more has he tended to talk in terms such as “immunity” and “metabolism,” “ecology” and “syndrome,” “homeostasis” and “pattern”—every one of them describing not so much a property of matter or quantity itself as harmonious order, every one therefore essentially an aesthetic term.  


The psychologist today talks about “Gestalt,” “ego,” “personality” or “behavior”—terms that could not be found in serious works before 1910.

The social sciences talk about “culture,” about “integration” or about the “informal group.”

And all talk about “forms.”

These are all concepts of a whole, of a pattern or of a configuration which can be understood only as a whole.  


These configurations can never be reached by starting with the parts—just as the ear will never hear a melody by hearing individual sounds.

Indeed, the parts in any pattern or configuration exist only, and can only be identified, in contemplation of the whole and from the understanding of the whole.

Just as the same sound in a tune rather than C# or A, depending on the key we play in, so the parts in any configuration—whether the “drives” in a personality, the complex of chemical, electrical and mechanical actions within a metabolism, the specific rites and customs in a culture, or the particular colors and shapes in a nonobjective painting—can only be understood, explained or even identified from their place in the whole, that is in the configuration.  


Similarly, we have a “Gestalt” pattern as the center of our economic life, the business enterprise.

“Automation” is merely a particularly ugly word to describe a new view of the process of physical production as a configuration and true entity.

“Management,” similarly, is a configuration term.

In government we talk today about “administration” or “political process”; the economist talks about “national income,” “productivity” or “economic growth,” much as the theologian talks about “existence.”

Even the physical sciences and engineering, the most Cartesian of all our disciplines in their origins and basic concepts, talk about “systems” or—the least Cartesian term of them all—about “quantum” in which, in one measurement, are expressed mass and energy, time and distance, speed and direction, all absorbed into a single indivisible process.  


The most striking change perhaps is to be found in our approach to the study of speech and language—the most basic and most familiar symbol and tool of man.

Despite the anguished pleas of teachers and parents, we talk less and less about “grammar”—the study of the parts of speech—and more and more about “communications.”

It is the whole of speech, including not only the words left unsaid but the atmosphere in which words are said and heard, that alone communicates.

It is only this whole that has any existence at all in communications.

One must not only know the whole of the message, one must also be able to relate it to the pattern of behavior, personality, situation and even culture in which communication takes place.  


These terms and concepts are brand-new.

Not a single one of them had any scientific meaning fifty years ago, let alone any standing and respectability in the vocabulary of scholar and scientist.

All of them are qualitative; quantity in no way characterizes them.

A culture is not defined by the number of people who belong to it, or by any other quantity; nor is a business enterprise defined by size.

Quantitative change matters only in these configurations when it becomes qualitative transformation—when, in the words of the Greek riddle, the grains of sand have become a sand pile.

This is not a continuous but a discontinuous event, a sudden jump over a qualitative threshold at which sounds turn into recognizable melody, words and motions into behavior, procedures into a management philosophy, or the atom of one element into that of another.

Finally, none of these configurations is as such measurable quantitatively or capable of being represented and expressed—except in the most distorted manner—through the traditional symbols of quantitative relationships.  


None of these new concepts, let me emphasize, conforms to the axiom that the whole is the result of its parts.

On the contrary, they all conform to a new and by no means yet axiomatic assertion, namely that the parts exist in contemplation of the whole.

 

bbx The Purposeful Universe

Moreover, none of these new concepts has any causality to it.

Causation, that unifying axis of the Cartesian world-view, has disappeared.

Yet it has not, as is so often said, been replaced by the random and happenstance.

Einstein was quite right when he said that he could not accept the view that the Lord plays dice with the universe.

What Einstein was criticizing was only the inability of the physicists—including himself—to visualize any concept of order except causality, that is, their inability to free themselves of their own Cartesian blinders.

Underlying the new concepts, including the new concepts of modern physics, is a unifying idea of order.

It is not causality, though, but purpose.


Every one of these new concepts expresses purposeful unity.

One might even state as a general principle of all these postmodern concepts that the elements (for we can no longer really talk of “parts”) will be found so to arrange themselves as to serve the purpose of the whole.

This, for instance, is the assumption that underlies the biologist’s attempts to study and to understand organs and their functions.

As a distinguished biologist, Edmund W. Sinnott, puts it (in his The Biology of the Spirit): “Life is the imposition of organization on matter.”

It is this arrangement in contemplation of the purpose of the whole that we mean today when we talk of “order.”

This universe of ours is thus once again a universe ruled by purpose—as was the one which the Cartesian world—view overthrew and replaced three hundred years ago.


But our idea of purpose is a very different one from that of Middle Ages and Renaissance.

Their purpose lay outside of the material, social, psychological or philosophical universe, if not entirely outside of anything man himself could be, could do or could see.

Our purpose, by sharp contrast, is in the configurations themselves; it is not metaphysical but physical, it is not purpose of the universe, but purpose in the universe.


I read a while ago a piece by a leading physicist in which he talked about the “characteristics of subatomic particles.”

A slip of the pen, to be sure; but a revealing one.

Only a half-century ago it would not have been possible for any physicist, no matter how slipshod, to write of anything but the “properties” of matter.

For atomic particles to have “characteristics,” the atom—if not matter and energy altogether—must have a “character”; and that presupposes that matter must have a purposeful order within itself. 





«§§§»

 

 

The new world-view, in addition, assumes process.

 

Every single one of these new concepts embodies in it the idea of growth, development, rhythm or becoming.

 

These are all irreversible processes—whereas all events in the Cartesian universe were as reversible as the symbols on either side of an equation.

Never, except in fairy tales, does the grown man become a boy again, never does lead change back to uranium, never does business enterprise return to family partnership.

All these changes are irreversible because the process changes its own character; it is in other words self-generated change.


Only seventy-five years ago the last remnant of pre-Cartesian thinking, the idea of spontaneous generation of living beings, was finally laid to rest by the researches of Louis Pasteur.

Now it comes back to us in the research of respectable biologists who look for clues to the origin of life in the action of sunlight and cosmic particles on amino acids.

Now respectable mathematical physicists seriously talk about something even more shocking to the Cartesian world-view; a theory of constant and spontaneous generation of matter in the form of new universes and new galaxies.

And a leading biochemist, Sir Macfarlane Burnet, the Australian pioneer of virus research, recently (in the Scientific American of February, 1957) defined a virus as “not an individual organism in the ordinary sense of the term but something that could almost be called a stream of biological pattern.”


In this new emphasis on process may well lie the greatest departure from the world-view of the modern West that has been ruling us for the last three hundred years.

For the Cartesian world was not only a mechanical one, in which all events are finitely determined; it was a static one.

Inertia, in the strict meaning of classical mechanics, was the assumed norm.

In this one point the Cartesians, otherwise such daring innovators, were the strictest of traditionalists.


It had been an accepted doctrine ever since Aristotle that the Unchangeable and Unchanging alone was real and alone was perfect.

The proudest achievement of the Cartesian world-view was to make this traditional axiom usable.

Motion so obviously exists; yet on the basis of the axiom of the primacy of immobility it can simply not be explained, understood and measured—as was first pointed out two thousand years ago in the famous paradoxes of Zeno, such as the paradox of Achilles and the tortoise.

Only calculus (together with Descartes’ own Analytical Geometry the foundation of modern mathematics, and the first result of the new, Cartesian world-view of the seventeenth century) could find a way out of the impasse between the axioms of immobility and inertia and the experience motion.

This it did by the most ingenious trick: by explaining and measuring motion as an infinite number of infinitely small and perfectly static “stills.”


It is far from true that this solved Zeno’s paradox as the textbooks assert.

Indeed we are becoming only too painfully aware today that the solution is inapplicable to genuine movement, that is to development—whether it be biological or economic growth—which cannot be explained away as a kind of optical illusion.

But for three hundred years the modern world-view could do what no one before had been able to do—assert the axiom of inertia and yet handle motion with growing assurance.

It could point to its success in analyzing, predicting and controlling motion as evidence of the validity of its axiom of the immovable and the unchangeable as alone perfect and real.

 

 

In our idea of process, however, we assume — and are increasingly conscious of the assumption — that it is growth, change and development that are normal and real, and that it is the absence of change, development or growth that is imperfection, decay, corruption and death.

 

We are breaking, therefore, not only with the “obvious” common sense of the world-view of the modern West, but with much older and much more fundamental Western traditions.

 

Introduction

 

bbx Toward a New Philosophy

These new concepts have, within the last twenty or thirty years, become the reality of our work and world, if not the small talk of the popular newspaper.

They are obvious to us.

Anyone rash enough to suggest that they are anything but obvious, and are indeed almost incomprehensible—methodologically, philosophically and metaphysically—would at best be stared at as an egghead and more likely be curtly dismissed as a hairsplitter.


There are beginnings toward the new synthesis we need—in biology and physics, in operations research and modern mathematics, in general systems theory, in semantics, linguistics and mathematical information theory.

We are beginning to move from the old mechanical concept of discipline as determined by static properties of the subject matter, to new disciplines dealing with such universal configurations and processes as “growth,” “information” or “ecology.”


Anticipation of the new vision can be found in many great thinkers—Aristotle, Leonardo, Goethe, Bergson, Whitehead.

The first to comprehend it, however, was probably that astounding South African, Jan Christiaan Smuts—the closest to the “whole man” this century has produced—with his philosophy of Holism twenty-five or thirty years ago.

Physicists increasingly grope for it, as do Lancelot Law Whyte in his The Next Development of Man and Erwin Schroedinger, the Nobel Prize winner, in his What Is Life?

The latest and most persuasive expression of the new view is The Image, by the distinguished economist Kenneth Boulding.

The contemporary philosopher whose books sell best in paper-back editions in the United States is the late Ernst Cassirer, though his works are anything but popularly written—indeed a veritable thicket of Teutonic abstractions.

His writings deal with patterns, configurations and symbols of order as the essential human experiences.


Yet though we take the new world-view increasingly for granted, we do not yet understand it.

Though we talk glibly of “configuration,” “purpose” and “process,” we do not yet know what these terms express.

We have abandoned the Cartesian world-view; indeed it is rapidly becoming almost incomprehensible to us.

But we have not, so far, developed a new synthesis, a new toolbox of methods, or new axioms of meaning, order and inquiry.

We have certainly not yet produced a new Descartes.

As a result we are in intellectual and aesthetic crisis in every area.


The people working in a given discipline see the new process and configuration concepts; indeed, they often see little else.

But for rigorous work they have only methods based upon the old worldview and the old concepts, methods which are quite inappropriate to the new vision.


In the social sciences this lag shows itself in the glaring discrepancy between the talk of “culture,” “personality” or “behavior” and the inability to produce much more than vast collections of empirical data about particular—and by definition meaningless—manifestations.


In a discipline that is much closer to my own daily interest, the study of management, the situation is equally frustrating.

The discipline only exists because we have configuration concepts such as “business enterprise” and “the process of managing.”

All of us stress that the really important things are process-characteristics, such as the climate of an organization, the development of people in it, or the planning of the nature and purposes of a business enterprise.

But whenever we try to be scientific we are thrown back either on purely mechanistic and static methods, such as work measurement of individual operations, or at best on organization rules and definitions.


Or take the physicists: the more they discover about the various subatomic particles of matter, the more confused, complicated and inconsistent become their general theories of the nature of matter, energy and time.


 

 

Another result is that the very disciplines that are advancing the fastest, in which therefore there is the most to learn, are rapidly becoming unteachable.


There is no doubt that medicine has made giant strides during this last generation.

But every experienced teacher of medicine I know wonders whether the young medical school graduate of today—the same one who gets “the best medical education the world has to offer”—is as well taught and as well prepared as his more ignorant predecessor thirty years ago.

The reason is simple.

Medical schools are still organized around the idea of disciplines as static bundles of knowledge.

A hundred years ago, when the modern medical school came into existence in Paris, Vienna and Berlin, there were at most six or seven such “bundles.”

But there are fifty or more today.

Each has become in its own right a full-blown science, which it takes a lifetime to master; even to acquire a smattering of ignorance in any of them takes more than the five years of medical training.


This crisis, it should be firmly said, is not the natural result of advancing knowledge as some academicians assert.

The natural result of advancing knowledge should be, as it has always been, greater simplicity—and greater ease of understanding, learning and teaching.

This is the first, if not the foremost, aim in advancing knowledge.

That our knowledge becomes constantly more specialized, more complicated, rather than more general, proves that something essential is lacking—namely a philosophical synthesis appropriate to the world we inhabit and see.


What may well be the most serious affliction of this time of philosophical transition is the maddening confusion of tongues among the various disciplines, and the resulting cheapening and erosion of language and style.

Each discipline has its own language, its own terms, its own increasingly esoteric symbols.

The unity of the universe is gone for twentieth-century man—for the first time, perhaps, since Thomas Aquinas, seven hundred years ago, wove together into one pattern the religious and the secular heritage of Western Christianity.

Whenever we try to reestablish such a unity all we can do is to go back to Cartesian, that is to ultrapositivist or mechanistic concepts of the world, which deny the very insights and knowledge that make the unification desirable and indeed necessary.


No wonder that the layman is confused, bewildered and sullen.

We hear a great deal today about the anti-intellectual public.

But what else can the public be if it cannot understand?

Yet to understand, it would need the unifying general concepts which the experts themselves do not have.


Fortunately we already can foresee—as only a decade or two ago we could not—what form the new integration will take.


We can see first what it will not be.

It will go beyond and encompass the Cartesian world-view rather than repudiate it.

The great shift to the Cartesian world-view became necessary because its predecessor, scholasticism, had become sterile and had ultimately failed.

The new worldview, however, has become necessary largely because of the great success of its predecessor, the mechanistic, positivist Cartesian “Science.”

We are abandoning the whole-parts concept of the Cartesian world-view, its mechanical causality, its inertia axiom.

But while modern physics leads us, for instance, to rediscover Aristotle on an entirely new level of understanding, it does not make us any more appreciative of astrology.

Modern biology and modern Operations Research make us conscious of the need to accept and to measure quality, value and judgment.

They have not made us repudiate strict methods of demonstration and proof or abandon the quest for impersonal measurement.


Another negative conclusion: the Cartesian dualism between the universe of matter and the universe of the mind will not be maintained in the new integration.

It was never fully accepted in this country.

But it was certainly the most potent, as it was the most central, part of Descartes’ own system.

For three hundred years it has paralyzed philosophy—if not thinking altogether—by creating meaningless but increasingly bitter splits between idealist and positivist, with each building ever-higher spite fences around his own little plot of reality.


If there ever was a useful distinction here, it ceased to be meaningful the day the first experimenter discovered that by the very act of observing phenomena he affected them.

Today our task is to understand patterns of physical, biological, psychological and social order in which mind and matter become meaningful precisely because they are reflections of a greater unity.


We can also say affirmatively what the new integration needs to be.


It must give us a concept of the “whole” as a universal and yet specific reality—whether it be “system,” “organism” or “situation.”

We need a discipline rather than a vision, a strict discipline of qualitative and irrevocable changes such as development, growth or decay.

We need rigorous methods for anticipation of such changes.

We need a discipline that explains events and phenomena in terms of their direction and future state rather than in terms of cause—a calculus of potential, you might say, rather than one of probability.

We need a philosophy of purpose, a logic of quality and ways to measure qualitative change.

We need a methodology of potential and opportunity, of turning points and critical factors, of risk and uncertainty, constant and timing, “jump” and continuity.

We need a dialectic of polarity in which unity and diversity are defined as simultaneous and necessary poles of the same essence.


This may sound like a big order—and one we are as yet far from being able to fill.

Yet we may well have the new synthesis more nearly within our grasp than we think.

On it are based powers we already exercise: the power to innovate, and the power to harmonize individual and society in a new dynamic order.


If there is one thing we have learned, it is the truth of the old injunction of the seventh-grade mathematics teacher: Don’t worry about getting the right answer; what matters is setting up the right problem.

In philosophy, science and methodology—and even more perhaps in art—a problem begins to be solved the moment it can be defined, the moment the right questions are being asked, the moment the specifications are known which the answers must satisfy.

For then we know what we are looking for, what fits and what is relevant.


And that, in one after another of the areas of human endeavor, we already know.

 

From Progress to Innovation (PDF)

bbx 1 The New Perception Of Order

bbx The Research Explosion

bbx Man and Change

bbx Innovation and Knowledge

bbx The Power of Organized Ignorance

bbx 2 The Power of Innovation

bbx The Open-Ended Technology

bbx From Reform to Social Innovation

 

bbx 3 Innovation—The New Conservatism?

Innovation is risk.

Present resources are committed to future, highly uncertain results.

Present action and behavior are subordinated to the potential of an as yet unknown and uncomprehended future reality.


Innovation can best be defined as man’s attempt to create order, in his own mind and in the universe around him, by taking risk and creating risk.

It can be defined as the organized, indeed deliberate, seeking of risk to replace both the blind chance of premodern times (as symbolized in the Renaissance belief in Fortuna as the presiding genius of human destiny) and the certainty of the more recent but still outdated belief in inevitable progress, both chanceless and riskless.


This is bold, very bold.

It entails not just one heavy risk, but three: the risk of being overtaken by innovation, which one might call the risk of exposure; the risk of failure of the innovating attempt; and, heaviest of all, the risk of innovation’s success.

 

bbx The Risks of Innovation

Innovation can change, almost overnight, the established order, render obsolete what only yesterday seemed impregnable, make dominant what only yesterday was negligible.


Economists tell us that the large business enterprise of today has a built-in momentum that may give it an advantage way beyond anything deserved by efficiency or managerial excellence, and may keep it strong, powerful and big long after it has ceased to be aggressive and competitive.

There is something in this.

Yet, of the hundred largest manufacturing companies in the United States only thirty years ago, more than half have disappeared from the list today.

Some have vanished altogether, others have fallen way behind.

Their places have largely been taken by companies which, thirty years ago, either did not exist at all or were insignificant.

The newcomers owe their present position not to financial manipulation but to new technology, new processes or new products—that is, to innovation.


The risk of exposure in innovation changes the nature of international politics and international economics.

There is always present the possibility of a sudden landslide that can completely alter the international landscape and the position and balance of forces.

This might be a change in the international economy, in international resource-geography or transportation-geography.

It might be a change in political constellation, in military or industrial balance of power, or national policy—all capable of changing, almost overnight, the international position of a whole country, even of the biggest and mightiest.


Such dramatic changes have of course occurred throughout history—but they came fairly infrequently.

The cause may have been that mysterious historical event, one nation’s decline in vigor or another nation’s sudden outburst of creative energy.

It may have been foreign invasion or a sudden shift in trade routes.

Once in a long while it was the result of new technology, especially military technology.

But what was rare “turning point” in the past has now become ever-present danger.

What happened as by-product is now capable of being purposeful goal.

What was Fortuna, in other words, is now risk.


This not only applies to a country internationally.

It applies fully as much to institutions, groups and forces within a country, within an economy.

Each technology, each industry, each business lives under the risk of being made obsolete without warning, of being destroyed or damaged by innovation, technological or social.


This risk cannot be avoided.

On the contrary, any attempt to prevent innovation, even any attempt to ignore it, can only make the risk greater.

Nor can the risk be shrugged off as “all in the day’s work.”

It must be accepted and provided for. 




«§§§»


Little needs to be said about the second risk in innovation, that of failure.


Innovation must anticipate the future and must commit resources, efforts and destinies to this anticipation.

But no human being can possibly predict the future, let alone control it.

Innovation must therefore have a high failure rate.

It may fail because the innovation was faulty in vision, insufficient in design or premature in timing.

It may fail because of inability to produce the planned results or to produce them in the available time.

Or—perhaps the cruelest but also the most common risk—the innovating attempt may succeed brilliantly, only to be obsolete by the time it is completed, overtaken by events, by the growth of knowledge, or simply no longer appropriate.

Thus very few of the main lines of medical research that would have appeared to a well-informed man as most important and most promising thirty years ago have contributed much to the great medical advances since.


These two risks lead to a paradoxical conclusion.

More and speeded-up innovation alone can protect against the risk of being overtaken by the innovation of others.

But this necessity only commits even more resources to a gamble in which failure is more probable than success. 




«§§§»


Yet, both the risk of exposure and the risk of failure are minor compared to the third risk: that of the success of innovation.


Innovation does not create new laws of nature.

It is not even primarily concerned with finding such laws.

It aims, however, at directing and channeling the forces of nature according to human needs and human vision.

It aims furthermore at directing and channeling the values, beliefs, institutions and human resources of society according to those needs and that vision.


What impact beyond the desired one will a successful innovation have?

What new and unexpected changes will it produce?

What will it do to the fabric of society, its beliefs, its bonds of community?


A minor example: The development of effective insecticides such as DDT was rightly considered a great achievement.

It made possible the truly innovating vision of control of disease-bearing and destructive pests.

But unexpectedly, the new insecticides killed beneficial insects as effectively as destructive ones, bees as well as malaria-bearing mosquitoes.

This unforeseen result not only threatens bird life deprived of its food; it threatens all the trees and flowers—among them our major fruit trees—dependent on insects for pollination.


Innovation is thus not only opportunity.

It is not only risk.

It is first and foremost responsibility.

No one is responsible for chance; no one can do anything about it.

One can only welcome inevitable progress or bemoan it; at most one can attempt to delay it.

But innovation is deliberate choice; and we are responsible for its consequences.


The essential choices are between values, in respect both to aim and to means.

Precisely because it makes technology and social structure open-ended, innovation poses the continuous question what its values are.

Should we aim at strengthening our traditions or at weakening them?

Should we aim high or be expedient?


There may be areas where the values are given and outside the innovating decisions.

Industrialists in a free economy might claim that they must and do operate under an objective rule of profitability.

Industrialists in a socialist economy might similarly claim that production determines their decisions.

Neither is a clear and unambiguous measure.

Profitability over the long run is, for instance, something quite different from profits this year or next; the difference is one of basic values.

Similarly production may be measured by units, value, quality or cost—and all Soviet sources indicate that there is as much disagreement over the concrete meaning of production in that country as there is in a free economy over profitability.


But inevitable to all social innovation is a value decision in respect to the objective, the specifications selected, the institution built and the methods chosen.

Every social innovation—whether by government or school district, business or labor union—expresses a view of what man and society are and what they ought to be.


Innovation is therefore always ethics—as much as it is intellectual process and aesthetic perception.

It needs ethics (as a perceptive book⁠1 recently pointed out) as much to decide what value considerations are relevant as to decide which are right.

Traditional ethics, regardless of school, looked for the right response to a given situation.

We need ethics today that concern themselves with the problems of creating the right situation.

Ethics, most philosophers would agree, have been rather arid since Spinoza, though hardly for want of books written on the subject.

The climate of “inevitable progress” could not have been congenial to a discipline that assumes choice to be both relevant and rational.

Now, perhaps, we can expect new fundamental and fruitful work in ethics—we certainly need it.

1 * Ethics for Policy Decisions by W. A. R. Leys, New York, 1952.

 

bbx Plan or No Plan?

The risks and responsibilities of innovation require themselves major innovations.

The first risk, that of exposure to innovation, makes planning necessary.

The second risk, that of failure in innovation, prohibits, however, any central planning and demands a competing multiplicity of local plans.

The third risk, that of the impact of successful innovation, demands a new attitude to change, a new politics of change in society.

It demands essentially a new conservatism.


Twenty-five years ago an English Socialist economist, Barbara Wootton, wrote a pamphlet, Plan or No Plan, which had a profound impact on public and policy-makers, at least in the English-speaking countries.

Her thesis was simple: Planning is a necessity; therefore centralized Socialist dictatorship, controlling alike society and economy, is a necessity.

For the only alternative to centralized planning by fiat from above is the mad, self-destructive chaos of “no plan.”


There were quite a few things wrong with the argument even then—it was naïve to the point of being disingenuous.

But the syllogism appeared almost a truism only a few short years ago—and by no means only to Communists and Socialists.

In those days American business also shared the view.

The National Recovery Administration (NRA) through which, with enthusiastic business support, Franklin D. Roosevelt first attempted to overcome the Depression, was in essence centralized planning from above for the entire economy.


Today even the Communists, to judge by Russia’s recent actions, have considerable doubt.

The rest of us have none.

Wherever the people in a country that had experienced centralized planning were given a free choice—in most of Western Europe for instance—they repudiated it.

They had seen how little resemblance the reality of planning from above bears to the theoretical picture of an orderly and harmonious efficiency.

But the alternative to planning by centralized fiat is not “no plan.”

It is planning by self-control.


Wherever we look today, we see planning.

Long-range planning is the central theme of today’s businessman.

Every day my mail contains yet another speech or article on the long-range planning of a well-known company—in English, in German, in French, in Italian, in Dutch, in Spanish or Portuguese or in Japanese.

Company after company is setting up a long-range planning department.

And so is city after city.


Most universities work on a long-range plan.

So do hospitals and school districts, research laboratories, professional societies, newspapers and magazines, international bodies, the military, political parties, government departments and law firms.

Indeed long-range planning threatens to become something of a fad.

There is more than a grain of truth in the Washington gibe: “We don’t want to do the job so let’s set up another long-range planning study.”


In many cases planning is still weak in its understanding of the job and of the methods used.

There is the tendency to confuse planning with the futile attempt to outguess the fluctuations of the business cycle.

There is the tendency to try to do planning by projecting the trends of the past into the future whereas the starting point of planning must always be the recognition that the future will be different.

There is the all-too-common belief that planning eliminates risk—the most dangerous delusion of all, since planning is actually risk-creating and risk-taking.


But there is also a growing understanding of the nature and function of planning, and growing knowledge of the proper tools and methods.

We are learning the difference between planning and prediction or forecast, and between what we would like to see happen and what we can try to make happen.

We are learning the difference between blind gambling and rational choice among risks based on informed judgment.

We are learning that the aim of planning is not to perpetuate the present but to anticipate and force the new.

The purpose is innovation.


Above all we are learning that the only protection against the risk of exposure in innovation is to innovate.

We can defend ourselves against the constant threat of being overtaken by innovation only by taking the offensive.

The best statement of this new attitude comes perhaps from the world of business: The time to change the theory of the business on which a company operates, and to innovate in respect to its character, function, objectives, product, market and organization, is when the company is most successful and most profitable.

For every theory of the business eventually becomes obsolete.

If a company waits until it starts to go downhill, it has usually waited too long.


This process requires an attitude that has been far from common.

It requires that rarest of human insights: the willingness to question one’s own success.

But it is the only attitude that can make productive—can indeed make bearable—the risk of innovation.

It is easy, for instance, to think through a country’s foreign policy when it has failed—any editorial writer can do that.

It is much more difficult to innovate a new concept of the country’s foreign policy when the present one is highly successful.

Yet this is the only way to prevent failure.

And the aim of long-range planning is to make effective this attitude in an organized, systematic, continuous effort of innovation.

 

bbx Local Plan or No Plan

Because of the risk of innovation our choice is not between centralized plan and no plan but between centralized plan and localized plan.

But the risk of failure in innovation converts this into a choice between local plan (which alone can work) and no plan, into which central planning degenerates.


The risk of failure in innovation makes centralized planning impossible, indeed converts it into chaos and tyranny, and makes its certain outcome collapse.

The odds are simply too heavy against the success of any one plan.

We have to commit present resources to highly uncertain future results, stake our selves on our ability to perceive the as yet unknown and to do the as yet impossible.

Therefore we have to plan.

But to expect any one such plan to come out right is folly, and so is the expectation that any one group of planners will come out right no matter how many alternative plans they develop.

Elementary mathematics shows that the outcome of such a gamble must be worse than to have no plan at all and to play random chance.


At the same time the very stake in his planning forces the centralized planner to try to control everything; anything uncontrolled becomes a danger.

Centralized planners would probably tend to become tyrants anyhow; absolute power always hungers for more power.

But even if the planners did not want to tyrannize, centralized planning for the entire economy or for the entire society propels them inevitably toward it.

The more the central plan embraces, the riskier the venture, the greater the odds against its success.


The inability to foresee, thirty years ago, the recent breakthrough areas in medicine may, at first glance, sound like an argument against organized systematic innovation.

But the major breakthroughs that did occur were all the result of genuine innovation rather than of chance.

The breakthroughs would not have been made if one man, or one group of men, no matter how knowledgeable, responsible or wise, had been the central planners of medical research.

They were achieved only because the planning was multiple, pluralistic, autonomous, local.

The example is thus both a cogent argument against centralized planning and a cogent argument for local planning.


We are concerned here with control, not with ownership, with centralized planning rather than with nationalization (though the two may tend to go together).

Centralized planning by nationwide industrial cartel—such as Roosevelt’s NRA attempted—would be just as bad as centralized planning by the dictatorship of the proletariat.

Altogether this is not just a matter of the economy where it has traditionally been fought out, but of all innovation, technological and social, by economic, by political, or by cultural institutions.


There are, it should be said, qualifications.

As long as an economy is purely imitative of other, more highly developed economies—as Soviet Russia was and largely still is—centralized planning is possible.

It is wasteful.

It is beset with serious risks—Russia’s economy has broken down unnecessarily into famine, uncontrolled inflation or paralyzing purges every five years or so.

It is inevitably tyrannical.

But it is not impossible.

The moment, however, that innovation becomes as necessary as it is highly desirable, centralized planning becomes impossible.

It is no accident that the Russians are now busily engaged in decentralizing their planning.


Centralized planning is also possible where the objective is sharply defined, the planning period very short and the costs not very important.

The best example is war.

It is no accident that the very idea of planning came out of the experience of World War I, especially out of the work of the American and German War Industries Boards.

Even for war, however, experience argues against centralized planning for innovation; what can be planned centrally is the use of resources available, in existence and known.

One of Churchill’s strengths as a wartime leader was to understand this.

He centralized decisions, even on details, in his own hand.

He set up complete controls over existing resources.

But he encouraged, initiated, pushed and fought for decentralized, autonomous, competing planning for all innovations, technological, strategic and social.


The argument against central planning is not an argument against planning by the central organ—whether the government of a country, the general staff of an army or the top management of a business.

On the contrary, without effective planning by the central organ, planning altogether is impossible.

The central organ must plan in respect to its own jobs: foreign policy and defense in the case of a government for instance, or basic objectives, financial policy and organization structure in the case of a large business—for it too faces both the risk of exposure and the risk of failure in innovation.

In addition the central organ must represent the common interest in respect to local, autonomous planning.

It must co-ordinate, balance and guide.

It must make the final risk-taking decisions.

It must set standards of conduct and of performance.

Above all it must stimulate the local organs to plan rather than to drift.

But it must not be the planner, must not even insist on conformity in the local planning efforts, but rather encourage diversity, competition and independence.


There is plenty of room to disagree where the line should be drawn between the sphere and authority of the center in planning, and the sphere and authority of local planning.

We find this disagreement in international and national affairs.

It is a live issue in a university between the central administration and the faculties, departments and individual scholars, and in a large business between top management and divisions, functional staffs and individual managers or professionals.

There is also plenty of room for argument over the best pattern of co-operation, competition and autonomy between the pluralist innovating efforts of a society, a government, an army, a university or a business.

But the principle is simple and clear: The risk in innovation is too great to allow uniformity and centralization; it requires different, autonomous, alternative, competing, local efforts.


Despite all the ink spilled over it, central planning is no longer the real issue.

More real and much more difficult is the question: how “local” should local planning be?

If too small or too narrow, a local organ will have neither the vision nor the resources to plan for innovation.

If too large or too diverse, it will in itself become a central planner.


The Soviet Union has recently announced a policy of decentralizing planning by large geographic regions.

It is almost certain that this is wrong and will work badly.

On the one hand, the unit is both too large and too diverse.

On the other, it is also too small and too narrow—both for industries that are national in their economic character and for real technological innovation.

Peter Kapitsa, the Soviet Union’s most distinguished physicist—and by no means a friend of planning—warned publicly against the decentralization of technological research which, he predicted, would become subordinate to regional expediency and immediate need and thus slight real innovation.

Many managers of important businesses in the Soviet Union have at the same time—though much more discreetly—protested that the decentralization did not go far enough; the region is still a central planner whereas genuine local planning autonomy for each major business is needed.

To anyone familiar with government, armed services, universities or business in the Free World these arguments will sound familiar.


What makes the question of the best unit of local planning so difficult—but also so important—is that different purposes require different definitions of what “local” means and different organs for the job.

There is no formula; and there should be no uniformity.


This concept of local planning may seem disorderly, wasteful, illogical.

But the greatest planner of all knows otherwise.

Nature provides against the risks of life by multiplicity and competition.

It would be so much more orderly if there were only one plant and one animal.

But when the mighty dinosaurs succumbed to a change in environment, there were available some obscure, wretched creatures, ancestors of the present mammals, to take their place—for they had produced an apparently useless innovation: self-control of their body temperature.

It would be much less wasteful if the female frog laid only two or three eggs, or if there were just one sperm cell in the human semen to fertilize the female ovum.

But rather than eliminate the overwhelming odds against the embryo frog’s surviving to maturity or against the sperm’s reaching the ovum, nature provides millions of both.

And it is this multiplicity, this purposeful duplication, this result-focused logic, this cooperative competition, that is the true order.


Centralized planning was a first reaction to the new power of innovation and its new risks.

But it attempted to organize a manifestation of the post-Cartesian world-view by Cartesian means: Centralized planning sees the world as a machine.

Planning we need; but the risk in innovation alone forbids centralized planning and demands autonomous, competing, local innovation.

Centralized planning attempts to order our search for new vision and a new capacity of achievement on the model of mechanical order, the measure of which is efficiency.

But productive planning has to be modeled after a higher order—that of life, the measure of which is creativity.

The aim of innovation is not a static conversion of input into output but a dynamic transmutation of ignorance into knowledge and of impotence into power.

Its operational problem is not efficiency but risk.

 

bbx Innovation as Responsibility

Perhaps the most important—though the least tangible—consequence of innovation is the new responsibility it requires.

It is above all a political responsibility.


If value choice is both inevitable and meaningful, a genuine, constructive conservatism becomes both possible and necessary.

For then it becomes essential to take responsibility for the strengthening of basic values and the observance of fundamental principles; to demand respect for the historical roots of a society but to despise its self-glorification; to respect one’s fellow man but to know one’s own weaknesses, limitations and fallibility; to demand a high goal and to take the long view.

These are traditionally the qualities of the conservative temperament.


Conservatism found its profoundest spokesmen in the age of “inevitable progress”: Burke and Acton, John Adams, Marshall and Calhoun, Stahl and De Tocqueville.

It was the creed of great statesmen: Washington, Hamilton and Lincoln; Castlereagh and Disraeli; Metternich.

But it could not be fully effective as a political force—not even in the countries of the Anglo-American tradition—because it either became pure reaction or it resigned itself to the role of retarder and brake, rather than creative force.

Individual conservatives—George Washington is the great example in this country, Disraeli in England—could rise above this by becoming great and yet truly conservative innovators.

But conservatism as such could only be an antibody (though a badly needed one).

The age belonged to the liberal, the radical, the progressive, if not to the revolutionary.


Today both liberalism and conservatism in their traditional meaning are moribund.

Indeed ideological parties are probably obsolete and certainly meaningless.

And any revival of traditional conservatism is most unlikely.


We need something new: the conservative innovator, who accepts innovation and with it accepts, indeed asserts, responsibility for its risks and results.

Precisely because an age of innovation can no longer ask whether there should be change or even how fast, but only argue over what it should be, aim for and do, this may well be the age of those who believe that responsibility rather than success is the measure of man: the age of the conservatives.

 

Beyond Collectivism and Individualism

bbx The New Organization

The medieval morality play is staging a comeback.

During the last ten years our popular literature has become increasingly concerned with the ethics of human relations and the morals of power.

But the actors are no longer the great of the earth, the bishops and kings, merchant princes and feudal lords.

They are the great of organization: corporation vice presidents and battalion commanders in the army, engineers and sales managers.

They wear neither coronet nor miter, but carry brief case and slide rule; they are clearly middle class in income and wealth, mores and behavior.

Yet their struggles for power and position, and the ethics of their relationship, have become almost overnight an absorbing and popular topic.

They were the subject of Herman Wouk’s The Caine Mutiny.

Beginning with Executive Suite by Cameron Hawley, one popular novel after the other has focused on organization ethics in big business.

The popular and much-discussed American television play Patterns had the same topic.

Twenty or thirty years ago the most widely read books in the social sciences dealt with economics, psychoanalysis or cultural anthropology.

Now we have James Burnham’s The Managerial Revolution, Kenneth Boulding’s Organizational Revolution, William H. Whyte’s Organization Man and David Riesman’s The Lonely Crowd — all four dealing with the ethics of man in large-scale organization.

The two best-selling novels published in Soviet Russia during the short relaxation of thought control after Stalin’s death, Ehrenburg’s The Thaw and Dudintsev’s Not by Bread Alone, also dealt with the ethics and morality of men in the new organization.

In England this has been the main concern of at least one outstanding writer: C.P. Snow.

Himself a leading figure in the “new organization” (as Civil Service Commissioner in charge of scientific personnel), he has, in such novels as The Masters and The New Men, written searching studies of the problems of power, of responsibility, and of the behavior of men working together in organization.⁠1

The new organization is hardly yet seen in its full meaning and impact.

We take it for granted.

But we rarely realize that it represents a new capacity we have gained within the last generation.

Fifty short years ago, with few exceptions, only simple, repetitive, regimented work could be brought together in large-scale organization; any work requiring skill and knowledge, let alone judgment, could be performed only by the individual working alone.

 

Today we have the capacity to organize men of high skill and knowledge for voluntary, joint performance through the exercise of responsible judgment.

This is the new organization, the inevitable setting for the new, systematic innovation of our times.

This new organizing ability has already created a new social reality.

It has given us a new leadership group and a new leadership function: the employed professional specialist and the employed professional manager.

It creates a new central issue of power, demands a new organization ethics and a new organization law.

It creates a new social problem — the integration of the professional men, both specialists and managers, into the organization — which bids fair to become the social question of the twentieth century.

It creates the need and opportunity for a major new field of human knowledge, and for a major new discipline, that of managing.

This discipline should be, indeed must be, both systematic and humanist, both a special study and in itself a general, liberal education.

The new organizing capacity creates a middle-class society of men who are professionals in their work but rank as employees, managerial in their responsibility but middle class in their outlook, expectations, rewards, opportunities and values.

This professional middle class is becoming the characteristic, if not the dominant, group in every developed society.

Its emergence creates a new economics.

Organization knowledge and professional knowledge are becoming the real “factors of production”; “land, labor and capital,” the three factors of production of traditional economics, are increasingly becoming merely limitations on the effectiveness of knowledge.

Finally the new organizing capacity has by-passed the age-old fixed positions of individualism and collectivism alike, and is giving us a new vision of the nature of individual and of society, and of the bond between them.

This chapter will discuss this new organizing capacity and the new social reality that results from it.

1 * How recent all this concern is I myself can testify.

For the first attempt to study one of these new organizations was a book of mine: Concept of the Corporation.

When it appeared only twelve years ago (in 1946), the very idea that anyone could seriously study the big-business enterprise as a social institution, and management as a central social function in society and economy, was considered strange if not revolting.

bbx The Capacity to Organize

There may not be much substance to today’s common plaint that the ablest and best-educated college graduates increasingly look for their life’s work and career to a job in a large organization, especially the large business enterprise.

But two things are certain: First, the large organization — whether business, civil service or armed force — has developed an apparently insatiable appetite for men of skill, knowledge and responsible judgment.

Second, the young people of high skill and knowledge are increasingly convinced that what they have learned and know can be used effectively in the large organization, can be made productive in and through the large organization.

Obvious today, almost taken for granted, these are brand-new and radical facts.

They bespeak the new powers and capacities of large-scale organizations.

A good example of the new capacity to organize is today’s air base.

The traditional titles of rank of a military organization are of course still maintained.

The Table of Organization still portrays a neat downward flow of decisions, knowledge and orders from the commandant at the top who “gives the orders” to the soldiers and noncoms at the bottom who “obey the orders.”

But what orders can the commandant actually give to a crew chief who is in charge of maintaining the jet planes of a squadron?

Though only a sergeant, the crew chief applies his own skill and his own knowledge, both of a very high nature.

He uses his own judgment.

He, rather than the commandant or even the squadron commander, decides whether a plane can be flown and what has to be done to make it air-worthy.

The commandant can discipline the crew chief, can demote him, can replace him.

But he cannot “command” him; he can, at most, overrule him.

Indeed it is one of the major jobs of the commandant to make possible the fullest contribution of the crew chief’s skill and knowledge, the fullest exercise of his judgment.

Conversely the more the crew chief knows and the more responsibility he accepts, the greater is his usefulness and contribution.

There are literally thousands of such people of decision-making skill and self-governing judgment on a modern air base: fliers and meteorologists, radio men and doctors, armorers and photographers, metallurgists, statisticians, operations researchers and psychologists.

Each of them plies his own trade or profession.

At the same time he is a member of the organization, working closely with men of different skill and knowledge, informed in his work by the direction, quality and purpose of the organization and of the other men in it, and in turn having immediate impact on the direction, quality and purpose of the work of the entire organization and on its performance.

Such military organization is today increasingly typical.

Old-style military organizations may still be the major employers of men in all armed forces.

But the new branches, on which the fighting and striking power of a modern armed service increasingly depends, are all of the new type: the aircraft carrier, the armored division, the parachute battalion, and now the guided-missile unit.

How radical a break this is, is shown by the picture of Napoleon’s army in the movie made recently from Tolstoy’s War and Peace.

Here the French infantry attacks the Russian cannon on the heights of Borodino.

Unprotected, out in the open, the infantry marches up the hill: eight men to a line, eight lines to a square, eyes forward, two steps to the drumbeat.

Heads, arms, legs fly through the air; line after line is literally mowed down.

But those left standing keep on like automata, eyes forward, two steps to the drumbeat.

Napoleon’s generals well knew that it would have been both more effective and much less costly for the men to take cover and then race uphill between salvos in loose formation.

They even admired the occasional “irregulars” — such as the American Revolutionists — who could do this.

But they could not imitate them — no army could.

To organize large numbers of men for joint effort required “drill,” that is total subordination to iron routine, and indoctrination in one regimented behavior until it became a conditioned and compelling reflex.

This had been the principle of effective military organization all along.

Armies are the oldest large-scale organizations for joint effort; the conduct of war has, for thousands of years, been one task that could not be left to individuals or small, local communities operating on their own.

And for most of recorded history armies were the only large-scale organizations.

They were — from their first beginning at the dawn of recorded Egyptian, Chinese or Greek history until well into World War I — based on the repetitive, almost automatic discipline of drill, command and obedience.

Now this traditional and simple organization of command is rapidly being infiltrated by a new organization by responsible judgment.

The army is the most dramatic example of this new capacity to organize, because, having been based so long on the old ideas, it shows the contrast between the two so clearly.

But for the origin of the new concepts we must turn to a different and much younger institution: the business enterprise.

It is there that the new concepts were first — though dimly — perceived.

 

The earliest attempt can be found in the works of the students of business organization fifty years ago — such as Rathenau in Germany or Fayol in France.

A generation earlier, a few of the industrial masterbuilders of the late nineteenth century — Carnegie and Rockefeller in this country, Renold and Mond in England, Siemens and Abbe in Germany — had already been applying some of the principles in crude form.

But only in the last thirty years has the business enterprise, especially in its managerial structure, become the chief carrier and the chief developer of the new concepts.

Because it stands for the new capacity to organize, the business enterprise has emerged as a central institution everywhere, under free enterprise and under Communism, in developed countries and in underdeveloped ones.

This key position of business enterprise in the organizational revolution explains why the older institutions, the armed forces, the government service, even the Catholic Church, today increasingly look to the business enterprise as their model of organization, and try (sometimes rather unwisely) to apply the new principles of management to their own structure and operations.

 

This key role in developing the new capacity to organize has made business employment the preferred career for many able young people; even in the United States this represents a sharp change from the situation only a generation ago.

And yet even business enterprise, when it first emerged, depended on the old “regiment and drill” concept.

Certainly, the first effective large-scale organization for economic performance, that is for the production and distribution of goods and services, was based on this concept.

The pioneers of “Scientific Management” — such as Taylor and Gantt — groped for the new concept fifty years ago, and talked of tapping the human knowledge, individual responsibility and voluntary dedication of the worker.

But they could not do it.

Instead they gave us the assembly line.

Their achievement rested on their breaking down productive work into simple, repetitive, routine tasks.

It was the great and enduring contribution of Scientific Management to have seen that productive work, like fighting work, could be studied rationally, analyzed systematically and organized purposefully.

But then they organized through the same old regimentation and drill, and broke down jobs into repetitive, simple, mechanical motions.

The “assembly line robot,” that favorite manikin of the twenties and the thirties, was nothing but Napoleon’s soldier moved into Henry Ford’s plant.

 

Organization created energy and performance vastly superior to what any individual, no matter how skillful or how experienced, could have produced — just as the ancient Greek army of part-time, nonprofessional citizens, outperformed the professional “artists” of warfare who had met in single combat under the walls of Troy.

But fifty years ago we could not have organized had we not been able first to reduce work to drill, skill to obedience, knowledge to training, and cooperation to the assembly line.

Today the assembly line is obsolescent.

Today we know that even mechanical work is best organized as joint effort of men of high skill and knowledge exercising responsible, decision-making, individual judgment in a common effort and for a joint end.

This is the essence of automation as a concept of human organization for work.

Automation may well eliminate the unskilled worker from the production floor.

But it replaces him by an equal number of men of high skill and judgment: machinists, instrumentation specialists, programers, engineers, mathematicians, business analysts and so on.

Each of them works in his own field of knowledge with a broad discretionary area of judgment.

Each of them, however, must of necessity work closely with all the others — in constant communication with them, constantly adjusting to their decisions and in turn making decisions that affect their work.

The principles and concepts which automation applies to mechanical production work had earlier been developed for nonmechanical work in the business enterprise.

They are fast becoming the rule for all those who are not “workers” in the traditional usage of the word, but who labor productively as technicians, professionals and managers.

 

bbx Individual Work and Teamwork

The new organization is transforming work that was previously confined to individual effort.

It does not replace the individual by organization; it makes the individual effective in teamwork.

It has always been axiomatic that work of skill and knowledge, and above all work requiring judgment, has to be done by the individual on his own.

This "self-evident truth" was the basis of all individualist philosophy.

Insofar as organization was seen to apply at all, its purpose was to make it easier for the individual to work by himself and to produce his own individual results.

The finest example is the traditional university in which the individual scholar is given the greatest freedom of work and thought, and in which the institution provides the common student body, the physical plant, the housekeeping and the financial means to make fully effective an essentially self-contained effort of individuals who share only the commitment to intellectual integrity.

Similarly the modern research laboratory, as it emerged around 1850, made the individual master scientist more effective by supplying him with housekeeping and with trained assistants.

The Civil Service — also an invention of the nineteenth century — was at first designed to make effective the individual acting alone and by himself rather than in and through an organization.

The British Civil Service in India succeeded in running a whole subcontinent with a mere handful of men — never more than a thousand.

Each of them was on his own, usually after the briefest period of apprenticeship; he rarely even saw another official from one month to another.

Even the one big step beyond purely individual work of skill, knowledge and judgment did not change the accepted theorem.

This advance was functional specialization — the idea that one could organize a number of people of like skills and knowledge for group effort.

This concept came originally out of the military.

Since the eighteenth century different kinds of fighting work — infantry, cavalry or artillery — had been increasingly organized as separate branches.

This made possible great advances in the effectiveness of each branch and of the entire military organization.

But it required that the working together of different branches be held to a minimum.

Each developed its own skills, its own weapons, its own tactics, its own traditions, its own officer corps with its own education and careers; but they came together only in the plans and orders of a commander outside and above them.

And since even with functional specialization we could organize only very small numbers of people of skill and knowledge to work together, to advance meant of necessity constant fission of fields of knowledge into separate and separately organized specialties.

The same principle was followed when functional specialization came to be applied to the economic tasks of production and distribution — at about the same time that Scientific Management was applying the much older organizing principle to unskilled work.

In business too we could only organize work of skill and knowledge by setting it up in self-contained and isolated functions.

We still could not organize more than very small groups for joint effort, and were then forced to set up more and more separate and autonomous subfunctions.

Any of our business functions — whether engineering or accounting, manufacturing or marketing — shows the same limitations and underwent the same development.

In functional specialization, in other words, we tried to organize skill and knowledge work as if it were performed by one man — with each branch or department acting like one man in its relations to the entire organization and to all other branches and departments.

We never attempted to organize people of different skills and different knowledge, making different contributions, in one joint effort.

Contrast this with today's organization.

Contrast this for instance with the organization of the work that went into the production of the atom bomb, where thousands of high-grade professionals of all kinds of knowledge — physicists, mathematicians, chemists, design engineers, soldiers, procurement specialists, financial people, personnel people, production experts, and so on — worked together, organized not by functional specialization but by the stage of the project.

Increasingly this is becoming the preferred organization of our research laboratories.

Indeed it is the only effective organization for purposeful and systematic innovation.

In the army functional specialization, while still providing the background of education and career, is gradually giving way to interfunctional integration, for instance in the Regimental Combat Team.

Even in the university — the most specialized of all our organizations, and the one where, as a rule, department and specialty lines are most rigidly drawn — interdisciplinary courses and research are becoming increasingly common.

Here a number of scholars from different disciplines work together on a common subject matter to which each contributes his own knowledge.

In one of our large Eastern universities, for instance, there were in 1957 more than four hundred such interdisciplinary courses, studies, seminars or projects.

Among them was a course in Western civilization bringing together historians, philosophers, natural scientists, painters, musicians, political scientists and economists; a graduate seminar on labor problems run jointly by a lawyer, a cultural anthropologist, an economist and an engineer interested in automation; and a research project on electronic-computer design headed by a linguist and embracing psychologists, engineers, mathematicians and physiologists.

In business we have similar approaches.

For specific assignments we increasingly use the "task force" or the team composed of men from different functions and specialties working together.

For permanent operations we use decentralization which organizes within the business large numbers of men of different specializations for joint work, common performance and maximum contribution around an objective, common, nonfunctional concern, such as a line of products or a market.

 

The clearest example of the new team concept is the gradual transformation of the hospital.

When it first emerged from being a place for the poor to die in — Florence Nightingale and the Crimean War of 1854 were the turning point — it was organized as a facility for the individual master doctor.

The nurses existed to carry out his commands, the medical staff to assist him.

As late as 1880 even the "first assistant" in a major hospital had to wait for the "chief" rather than perform an operation himself or make a diagnosis.

This soon turned into functional specialization: Until quite recently, advances in hospital care resulted primarily from increasing specialization, and from the increasing isolation of specialty from speciality.

Today we have the diagnostic clinic in which specialists work together as a team — with the patient the unity rather than the specialized field of knowledge.

Increasingly nonmedical professionals are becoming partners in the team: dieticians, psychologists, social workers, biologists, physical therapists.

The nurse is changing from "servant" of the doctor into executive officer of the team — the one who co-ordinates the efforts, watches the patient, measures the effectiveness of the treatment, and so on.

In one large hospital, the nurse is given the diagnosis and the plan of treatment decided upon by the doctor in charge.

It is her job both to organize the efforts — to provide the medication, arrange for the clinical tests, mobilize dietician, therapist or psychologist — and to inform the doctor should the course of the illness deviate from the stated expectations.

Knowledge Work As A System

Indeed this shift of the nurse's role has gone so far that one order of Catholic nuns, founded expressly to nurse the sick, thinks of withdrawing from nursing.

"The change in the nurse's role is wonderful for the patient," says the Mother Superior, herself an experienced hospital administrator, "but we were not founded to serve the body but to serve God through being humble and through doing work that the world despises and spurns.

And now we all have advanced degrees.

Now we are becoming professionals and managers if not 'bosses.'"

Equally indicative of the change is the emergence of the hospital administrator — less and less often a medical man himself — as the "manager" of the large organization that today's hospital has become, and of hospital administration as an area of study in which we apply the new concepts of organization.

Perhaps most significant of all is the fact that today's doctor can hardly practice medicine any more unless he have access to, and membership in, the big, organized, managed joint effort that is today's hospital.

He has not ceased to be an individual professional; indeed the hospital multiplies his effectiveness as an individual professional.

But only in and through the organization can he any longer be effective as an individual; he has become as dependent on the organization as the organization used to be dependent on him.

Nowhere, it should be said, is the new organization yet to be found in perfect or pure form.

The new capacity to organize is everywhere still mixed in with old forms and concepts of organization.

Many doctors for instance still try to practice pretty much the way their grandfathers did; many hospitals are still organized as they were in 1910.

Most men in uniform in all countries are in organizations much closer to the basic concepts of Napoleon's infantry than to the needs of the modern air base.

Even at the air base the formal structure of organization is closer to tradition than to its own new needs or to its own informal but effective way of life.

The same is true of most small business.

Yet numbers are not very relevant; statistics tell us where we have been rather than where we are, let alone where we will be.

The institutions that are dynamic in, and characteristic of, our society are organizing on the new concept.

The social problems, the social ethics, the social knowledge of our age all are the problems, ethics and knowledge of the new organization.

 

bbx 2 From Magnate To Manager

bbx Specialist and Manager

bbx Power and Responsibility in Organization

bbx The Organization Man

bbx The Discipline of Managing

bbx 3 Beyond Collectivism And Individualism

bbx The Middle-Class Society

 

bbx Freedom in Dynamic Order

The philosophical dimension of a society, its principle of order, is much less tangible than sociological structure, status, opportunities or economic facts.

But it is far more powerful.

Sociological structure may determine how people act.

But the philosophical ideal of order determines why people act, what they expect and what they accept—their ideals and their values.  


The new organization changes our vision of the good society.

It implies a new ideal of man in society and gives to social order a new goal and meaning.

It makes untenable the fixed positions of social thought which we have occupied for centuries, the positions respectively of collectivism and individualism.  


The new organization is incompatible with either concept.

It must go beyond both, and develop a new expression for the relationship of individual to society.

The relationship will have to be one of mutuality rather than of opposition.

Individual and society will have to be seen as extensions, respectively, of each other, benefiting and strengthening, rather than limiting, each other.

Collectivism and individualism express static and mechanistic concepts of the social order (even the so-called “organic theory of state” is not organic at all but rather sees the biological body as a mechanical assembly).

The new organization expresses a dynamic order; it expresses a configuration of wins, decisions, responsibilities whose whole is much greater than the individual parts—but only if each “part,” each professional, takes true professional responsibility for the whole.  


Neither individualism nor collectivism was ever a very satisfactory concept of social order.

The basic limitation of individualism was the reality of organized society.

It is simply an obvious fact that collectives are not just aggregates of individual contracts for specific purposes but genuine entities that outlive the individual, have their own behavior, their own logic, indeed their own being.

There is something called “Germany,” and individuals are willing to die for it, no matter how contrary to their belief the collective acts or how little that entity serves their interest.  


The basic limitation of collectivism was always the reality of the individual.

A Hans Mueller could be destroyed by the collective called “Germany,” but he could not be entirely controlled by it and could not be contained within it.  


The either/or between collectivism and individualism has always been more rhetorical than real.

The two have always been slogans rather than genuine principles.

If treated as absolutes, they always became untenable in theory and unworkable in practice.

Every time they were carried through by the doctrinaires they collapsed into tyranny or dissolved into catastrophe.

But both were close enough to actual experience to serve as preferences; each was operational within the traditional power to organize.

Either was valid enough to serve as a fixed position from which to explore the central problem of freedom and order in human society.  


This is no longer possible.

It is no accident that the insight of “human relations” thirty years ago has had such an impact on our managerial thinking.

There is nothing remarkable in the perception that people in a work situation behave like people.

And yet this came as a shock both to the individualist, who had seen only the worker but not the community of work, and to the collectivists, who had seen only the common task but not the power and control of the individuals in it and over it.  


Today’s organization bases a collective—that is, a genuine social whole—on the individual acting as an individual and committing himself as an individual.

His act must be voluntary; the more of a “man” and the less of a “cog” the individual member, the stronger the organization.

The individual also needs internal, personal resources—of knowledge, of initiative, of responsibility, of values and of goals—way beyond anything an individualist society requires.  


But conversely the individual, in order to be effective as such, not only has to find access to the organization; he has to accept its reality, has to affirm its objectives and values, has to focus his values, knowledge and efforts on its needs and opportunities.  


The traditional view of social order, whether that of collectivism or of individualism, sees society and the individual as restraints or limits on each other.

At the best it seeks a compromise between them, through “concession” to society or to the individual.

In the new organization the two are functions of each other, mutually strengthening and complementing each other.

The traditional view, so to speak, subtracts society from individual or vice versa; the new organization multiplies the two.  


The more the individual in organization grows as a person, the more can the organization accomplish—the insight underlying all our attention to manager development and advanced manager education today.

But, conversely, the more the organization grows in seriousness and integrity, objectives and competence, the more scope is there for the individual to grow and to develop as a person.

This is a dynamic rather than a static relationship.

It is determined by a future state and future purpose and focused on the growth and development of both.  


No organization comes close to living this vision today.

We are confused, preach one thing and do another, guess, blunder, stultify.

But even the most mismanaged of our new organizations seeks for this concept and gropes for this vision even the most disorganized already measures its actions against this ideal of freedom in dynamic order, however dimly it perceives it, however rudely it understands it.  


The new organization deals with the relationship between individual and society, between freedom and order.

This makes it hazardous both if it fails and if it succeeds.

In this it shares the risk of all innovation.  


But it is also a challenge and an opportunity to overcome the old, sterile conflict between individual and society, between freedom and order, in a new synthesis.

This task demands social thought and political theory of high imagination and originality.

But at the same time it permits us to build the new social order on the best of our traditional values, and to live up to the best in our ideals.

 

The New Frontiers

No one born after the turn of our century has ever known anything but a world uprooting its foundations, overturning its values and toppling its idols.

No one younger than this century has known anything but an age of revolution.  


In the political, the social, the economic, even the cultural sphere, the revolutions of our time have been revolutions “against” rather than revolutions “for.”

The Revolution of Nihilism was the title of a best-selling book twenty years ago.

The specific application was to Nazism (the author, Herman Rauschning, had been a prominent Nazi politician), but the title would apply generally.

The revolutions of the twentieth century have been driven by enmity; 

they have been aimed at destroying rather than building; 

their slogans have been “death to” or at best “independence from” rather than “life for” or “freedom to.”

There were some exceptions: The New Deal owed its world impact in the gloomy thirties to its hope and positive faith, to its standing for rather than against.

But on the whole throughout this period the man — or party — that stood for doing the positive has usually cut a sorry and rather pathetic figure; well-meaning but ineffectual, civilized but unrealistic, he was suspect alike to the ultras of destruction and the ultras of preservation and restoration.  


Now, for the first time, in this age, there are new things to achieve; for the first time there is constructive work to do.

The Marshall Plan, to give an illustration, was designed to restore.

Its targets were Europe’s production figures of 1938, the last “peacetime” year.

Its aim was to undo the ravages of war and to go back to where Europe had been.

The official measurements of achievements used the prewar figures right to the end.

But virtually from the start, vision and goal shifted.

Almost everyone engaged in the effort, American and European alike, soon focused on building a new future rather than on restoring the past.

Everyone began to work on Europe’s potential, began to think about the institutions, habits, methods needed to create a new industrial economy and a new industrial society, and in the end, something even newer: a European community.

Soon this appeared to be the only practical approach; restoration and revolutionary overturning alike became impractical dreaming.  


Only a few years later we had forgotten that restoration had been the original aim; when President Truman in his Point Four program called for systematic action on a new task, the economic development of underdeveloped areas, he assumed that he was simply extending the Marshall Plan.  


We could not do anything like this in the twenties.

We could not do it in the thirties.

We could not even do it in the postwar planning that occupied so many good people in London and Washington during World War II.

We did not lack good will, knowledge, intelligence or even leadership.

We lacked tasks.

And now we have some.  


There are new frontiers outside and beyond both the established order and the revolutionary’s power-greedy vacuum.

There is need to build and room to build in—even if it is only in the open spaces left by the leveling of old structures.  


Increasingly these new frontiers are the realities of today.

It is there that the conflict between the Free World and Communist tyranny will largely be decided; increasingly the world conflict becomes a conflict over the leadership in the new tasks.  


There are four areas in which we face new demands: 

an intellectual area where a new “educated society” is emerging; 

an economic area in which economic development “up to poverty” presents both an opportunity of advance and unity and the danger of international and interracial class war, setting the underdeveloped against the developed peoples; 

a political area in which we face the need for new institutions of social order; 

and a cultural area in which the disappearance of the “East” as a viable culture and civilization has created a vacuum.  


Failure in any of these areas would be catastrophic—above all for the free West.

Only in the economic sphere do we yet know how the demands of the task can be met.

But in all four areas the work to be done can be defined.  


These areas of challenge, threat and opportunity to our post-modern world will be described in the next chapters.

The preceding chapters focused on perceptions, ideas and new capacities.

Now we are going to discuss policies.

So far we have asked: “What is the new reality?”

Now we shall ask: “And what does it demand of us?”

The Educated Society

bbx 1 The Educational Revolution

 

How to make the schools accountable

 

An abundant and increasing supply of highly educated people has become the absolute prerequisite of social and economic development in our world.

It is rapidly becoming a condition of national survival.

What matters is not that there are so many more individuals around who have been exposed to long years of formal schooling—though this is quite recent.

The essential new fact is that a developed society and economy are less than fully effective if anyone is educated to less than the limit of his potential.

The uneducated is fast becoming an economic liability and unproductive.

Society must be aneducated society today—to progress, to grow, even to survive.  


A sudden, sharp change has occurred

in the meaning and impact of knowledge

for society
.

 

Because we now can

organize

men of high skill and knowledge

for joint work


through the exercise of

responsible judgment,

the highly educated man

has become

the central resource of today’s society,

the supply of such men

the true measure

of its

economic, its military and even its political

potential.  


This is a complete reversal of man’s history within the last fifty years or so.

Until the twentieth century no society could afford more than a handful of educated people; for throughout the ages to be educated meant to be unproductive.  


A man who is now chief executive of one of America’s largest businesses did not dare admit when applying for his first job, in 1916, that he had an advanced degree in economics.

“I told the man who hired me that I had been a railroad clerk since I was 14,” he says, “otherwise I would have been turned down as too educated for a job in business.”

Even in the late twenties, when I myself started, commercial firms in England or on the Continent still hesitated before hiring anyone as a junior clerk who had finished secondary school.  


As late as the mid-forties, General Motors carefully concealed the fact that one of its three top men, Albert Bradley, had a Ph.D. continue

The Management Revolution

 

It has always been axiomatic that the man of even a little education would forsake the hoe and the potter’s wheel and would stop working with his hands.

After all our word “school”—and its equivalent in all European languages—derives from a Greek word meaning “leisure.”  


To support more educated people than the barest minimum required gross exploitation of the “producers,” if not strict rules to keep them at work and away from education.

The short burst of education in the Athens of Pericles rested on a great expansion of slavery, the intellectual and artistic splendor of the Italian Renaissance on a sharp debasement of the economic and social position of peasant and artisan.  


Idealists tried to break this “iron law” by combining manual work and education—the tradition goes back to the Rule of St. Benedict with its mixture of farmwork and study.

It found its best expression in the mid-nineteenth century, in Emerson’s New England farmer who supposedly read Homer in the original Greek while guiding a plow.

But this, of course, never worked.

The Benedictines—imperiling their salvation to the lasting benefit of mankind—very soon left farming to villeins and serfs and concentrated on study.

Long before Emerson’s death those New England farmers who cared for the plow had left both Homer and New England for the rich soils of the Midwest, while those few who had cared for Homer had left farming altogether to become lawyers, preachers, teachers or politicians.

The “iron law” was indeed inescapable as long as manual labor was the really productive labor.  


Thomas Jefferson believed in higher education and in equality as much as any American.

He considered the founding of the University of Virginia and the authorship of the Declaration of Independence, rather than the Presidency, his greatest achievements.

Yet in his educational master plan he proposed to limit access to higher education to a handful of geniuses.

It was obvious that only a few could be spared from manual labor.  


Today the dearth of educated people in the formerly colonial areas appears such a handicap as by itself to be adequate condemnation of colonialism and proof of the “wickedness” of the imperialists.

But education did not come first in the scale of social needs even fifty years ago; flood control and land boundaries, equitable taxation and improved agriculture, railroads and incorruptible magistrates, all ranked much higher.

If the colonial powers were then criticized on the score of education, it was for forcing it on too many, for destroying thereby the native culture, and for creating an unemployable, overeducated proletariat.

The educated person was then still a luxury rather than a necessity, and education a preparation for dignified leisure rather than for productive work.  


In my own childhood forty years ago, schools still assumed that education was for “nonwork.”

They preached that the educated man should not despise the honest worker as schools had preached since the days of Seneca in the first century.

evidence wall and timeline larger

evidence-wall-and-time-line-pict-600

“For almost nothing in our educational systems

prepares people

for the reality

in which they will live, work,

and become #effective” —

#Druckerism and intellectual capitalist #lms #education

How could an education system prepare us for unknown and unpredictable future #realitieS?

bbx The Scale of the Explosion

bbx The Impact on Society

bbx The Educational Competition

bbx 2 Society’s Capital Investment

bbx An Economic Analysis

bbx Teachers and Teaching

bbx How to Pay

bbx 3 Education For What?

bbx Society’s Stake

bbx The General versus the Special

bbx Learning by Doing

bbx The Educational Whole

bbx The Social Responsibility of Education

Up to Poverty

1 The Frontier of Development

bbx The Agents of Revolution

bbx The Promise and the Danger

bbx Is Economic Development Possible?

bbx The “Take-off Crisis”

bbx The Agriculture Problem

bbx Distribution and Credit

bbx “Social Overhead” Costs

bbx The Problem of Attitudes

bbx The Ultimate Resource

bbx 2 Building An Industrial Society

bbx The Role of Money

bbx Leadership by Example

bbx The Problems We Face

Modern Government in Extremis

bbx 1 The End Of The Liberal State

bbx The Definition of Modern Government

bbx The Rise of the Liberal State

bbx The Decline of the Liberal State

2 The New Pluralism

bbx The New Metropolis

bbx The Crisis of Government

bbx Pluralism and the Common Interest

The Vanishing East

bbx Success or Failure of the West?

bbx The Failure of the East

bbx Can the West and the New East Meet?

The Work to Be Done

Policies and actions in today’s world are already measured against the demands of the new frontiers; they are effective only as they answer to the new reality.  


Yet our policies and actions are still largely molded by the reality of yesteryear, still aim at solving yesterday’s problems, still assume yesterday’s world.

If we tackle the new at all, we tend to treat it as a “temporary emergency” that will go away again, or as a deviation from a norm that ought to be restored.

We tackle the new tasks as disturbances and problems rather than as opportunities.  


This, at bottom, is the crisis of the Free World — a crisis of vision and understanding, of leadership and realism.

We are in mortal danger not because we are weak but because we misdirect our strength to fight over yesterday’s battles and to repeat yesterday’s slogans.

bbx Our Self-Delusion

A symptom of our delusion is the belief that there would be no problems if only there were no Soviet Russia, and that there are no tasks other than the defeat of Communism.

Collage created using TurboCollage software from www.TurboCollage.com

Larger view  


Soviet Russia is a formidable enemy bent on world conquest.

It is an absolute necessity for the Free World to maintain its unity and military strength against the ever-present threat of Russian attack.

Kind words and good intentions can never substitute for power and preparedness in dealing with an avowed world conqueror.  


Communism is evil.

Its driving forces are the deadly sins of envy and hatred.

Its aim is the subjection of all goals and all values to power; its essence is bestiality: the denial that man is anything but animal, the denial of all ethics, of human worth, of human responsibility.  


But the great problems that face the world today are aggravated rather than caused by Soviet Russia or by international Communism.

If both were to disappear overnight, the tasks would remain the same.

The race for weapons of total annihilation, for instance, is not just the result of the conflict and tension between Russia and the West.

On the contrary, the conflict is to a large extent the result of the unmanageable explosion of military technology and of the resultant collapse of the international system based on nation-state and obsolescent modern government.

If military technology had not gotten out of hand, Russia, especially a Communist Russia, would still present a danger, and would still pose problems of defense in Europe and Asia alike.

But the problems could be managed by conventional means of diplomacy and strategy.  


To underrate the strength and achievements of an enemy is always folly.

Yet everything is true that has been said and written about the internal stresses and weaknesses of Communism.

Every glimpse we get into the Communist world, behind its façade of propaganda, shows sickness of the soul and torture of the body.

Every opportunity given to the subjects of a Communist regime to register their real feelings has revealed hatred and despair.

History knows no parallel to Hungary where an entire nation attempted to flee its homeland rather than stay under its own Communist government.

Poland and East Germany show the same profound repudiation as do the thousands of refugees—most of them pro-Communist only a few short years ago—who manage to escape into Hong Kong.  


We know that Communism’s greatest achievement tends to undermine the regime rather than strengthen it.

It is to her educational revolution that Russia owes her strength today.

Yet whenever the iron hand of police terror relaxes for a moment in any Communist country, the educated rebel.

The students, the writers, the scientists—the very group whom Communism cossets and on whom it showers privileges—led the Hungarian, the Polish, the East German risings.

The students, the writers, the scientists rose up in criticism when Communist China, in 1956, relaxed for a few weeks the iron controls on thought and speech.

The Communist rulers were right when they charged the educated with the high treason of repudiating Communism altogether.

But this only means that Communism cannot allow the educated to use their education, it can only tolerate technicians.

It finds itself, to use Marxist jargon, in a “basic contradiction”: It needs the educated man yet cannot tolerate him.

It needs the new organization of men of skill and knowledge yet cannot permit responsible judgment, let alone use the organization to promote human freedom.  


It suffers from a similar contradiction in respect to economic development.

A Communist government can survive only if it oppresses the farmer and suppresses rural society.

Yet it thereby undermines the agricultural foundation for economic development—and also freezes rural population at so high and yet unproductive a level as to endanger ultimate industrial growth.  


The great opportunity of Communism is, of course, the emergent nationalism of the formerly colonial people.

Yet Communism cannot allow independence.

It can tolerate only vassals and satellites.  


Above all, it is the prisoner of its own rigidly mechanistic orthodoxy which must be proclaimed infallible.

In the physical and natural sciences sheer necessity has forced the Communists to tolerate such heresies as quantum theory, nuclear physics and antibiotics—though even they were accepted only after considerable struggle.

But can even necessity make the Communists accept similar heresies in social and political affairs—the new organization, for instance?

Innovation with its risks and uncertainties and its need for decentralized, local, competitive planning?

Or political and social pluralism?  


The weakness of Communism, its internal contradictions incapable of resolution, its failure to build a society, are all shown up by one single fact: There has been no flight to the “Communist paradise.”

The Free World has no “people’s police” to prevent its citizens from crossing the border into the Communist world.

At every border point the flow of human misery runs in one direction only.  


And yet not only does disenchantment with Communism come perilously late, but the very failure of Communism constitutes its present danger.

For Communism is the exploitation of failure at the new tasks.

It is the opiate of the defeated and the drug of the irresponsible.  


Communism cannot accomplish the new tasks.

But it can, for a time at least, suppress the problems, deny their existence, forbid their discussion.

It cannot tolerate educated men, but it can breed technicians.

It cannot create a society, but it can organize power.

It cannot build an international order, but it can exploit disorder and make “crisis” permanent.

It cannot furnish the resources needed for economic development.

But it can channel despair and frustration into international and interracial class war.  


For the short run we do not have to fear the strength of Communism but its weakness.

In the long run, we do not have to fear the success of Communism but our own default.

It cannot triumph; but we may fail.

bbx The New Frontiers

 

The Human Situation Today

So far we have talked of the universes around man: the universe of perception and ideas, and the universe of political order and social institutions.

But man himself is a universe.

Where does man fit into this post-modern world?  


The universe of man has changed too—perhaps even more than the world around him.

Two essential and unique attributes of man—knowledge and power—have changed their very meaning.

As a result the meaning of man is changing.

And yet—as in our philosophical systems and our social and political institutions—our ideas, our methods, our preoccupations, our rhetoric, are still those of an earlier age which is fast becoming obsolete.

In respect to the human situation we are also on a voyage of transition.

We are still trying to steer by the old landmarks, even though we already sail new, uncharted seas.  


Twentieth-century man has achieved the knowledge to destroy himself both physically and morally.

This new absolute has added a new dimension to human existence.  


There is no danger that man will ever run out of ignorance; on the contrary, the more we know, the more we realize how little we know—in all areas of knowledge, in all sciences and all arts.

Yet the knowledge we have acquired is absolute knowledge giving absolute power.

There may well be even more “absolute” weapons of destruction than those we already possess.

But there is no going beyond total, final extinction; and that we can already inflict on ourselves.  


Man has always been expert at mass slaughter.

But even at their worst, his orgies of destruction were never “total,” there were survivors who could start afresh.

Even the worst slaughter was always quite localized.

Now we can, in a few seconds of mania, make the whole earth unlivable for all of us.  


By giving us this knowledge science has broken through to the core of human existence.

If we are to survive, we must learn to live with a new demon in ourselves, must master a new, absolute power in our hands, must face up to the constant threat of self-annihilation through knowledge.  


At the same time we are acquiring what is perhaps even more potent—and certainly even less controlled—knowledge: the knowledge to destroy man psychologically and morally by destroying his personality.  


It is common belief today that the sciences that deal with man’s behavior, such as psychology, have lamentably failed to keep pace with the advancement of the physical sciences.

This, alas, is delusion.

We have not, it is true, acquired the knowledge to make man better.

We have not learned very much, if anything, to enable man to control himself.

But we have learned how to make man worse.

We have acquired knowledge how to control others—how to enslave them, destroy them, dehumanize them.

And we are fast approaching the point where this too will become absolute knowledge capable of the total destruction of man as a moral being, as a responsible will, as a person.

We all but know enough today to turn man into a biological machine run by the manipulation of fears and emotions, a being without beliefs, without values, without principles, without compassion, without pride, without humanity altogether.

Through systematic terror, through indoctrination, lies and thought control, through systematic manipulation of stimulus, reward and punishment, we can today break man and convert him into brute animal.  


A behavioral science that does not aim at making man capable of self-control betrays man.

A behavioral science that does not affirm man as a rational and spiritual being betrays science.

Such a science produces destructive results that can only be abused and have no legitimate use.

But that does not affect the potency of the results.  


 

Totalitarianism is the final result of science without morality.

 

THE ALTERNATIVE TO TYRANNY

 

It is the systematic dehumanization of man, and the scientific exploitation of his animal nature.

It is no less “scientific” for being wicked and for being a travesty on all the hopes and beliefs of the scientists.

It systematizes old experience, as does any science; draws therefrom general theories of human nature; and then tests these theories in the large-scale experiments of concentration camps and terror, “brain-washing” indoctrination and thought control.

Nor does the inherent instability of all tyranny invalidate the power of the pernicious knowledge on which totalitarianism bases itself.

The knowledge is the danger;* and the knowledge remains available.

Here too is a new absolute.

Here too science has broken through to the core of human existence.

Here too we possess, however limited our knowledge, enough power for total self-destruction.

* On this see the discussion between two eminent American psychologists, C. R. Rodgers and B. F. Skinner in Science (Vol. 124, page 1057, December 1, 1956) which should cure any reader of the comfortable delusion that this is not “science” and that only evil but not “decent people like ourselves” will ever use it to enslave, manipulate and dehumanize. 

Skinner, undoubtedly well-meaning, proposes to manipulate people to be “adjusted” and “happy”; but this is just as much destruction of man for being well meant.

 

The knowledge to destroy man’s personality may have even greater impact on the human situation than the knowledge to destroy the physical life of the species.

 

That he must die, man has always known; every one of his major religions predicts the eventual extinction of the species.

 

But man, wherever and whenever he started to reflect, has always asserted that to be a man is something different from being mere animal, that to live like a man is more than to survive physically.

 

How can the individual survive?

Why bother?

 

On this assertion he has built his religions, his cultures, his civilizations, his arts, his sciences and his governments—everything of this world that is not buried with the individual animal remains.

 

The New Frontiers

The New Pluralism

 

It is this assertion that the totalitarian denies.

 

Freedom → Power is a reality →
The Alternative to Tyranny →
A revolution in every generation
is not the answer
continue

 

Google News Search: authoritarian

 

He maintains instead that man is a domestic animal—remarkably clever, to be sure, but also remarkably docile.

And he possesses enough knowledge of human nature to degrade man in the image of a domestic animal.  


 

 

For two thousand years the Christian has taken on faith and revelation the end of the world and the Anti-Christ.

Now the apocalyptic visions have become experience.

We can see the AntiChrist who turns all man’s fairest promises onto his perdition and all his hopes onto his enslavement.

And who among us today has not had the shock of knowing, if only in a nightmare, the moment of fiery cloud and deadly rain, the irreversible moment when a power-drunk dictator, a trigger-happy colonel, or a simple misreading of a “blip” on a radar screen will make us destroy ourselves?

bbx The Control of Power

bbx Knowledge and Human Existence

bbx Living in an Age of Overlap

... snip, snip ...

A time like this is not comfortable, secure, lazy.

It is a time when tides of history over which he has no control sweep over the individual.

It is a time of agony, of peril, of suffering—an ugly, hateful, cruel, brutish time at best.

It is a time of war, of mass slaughter, of depravity, of mockery of all laws of God or man.

It is a time in which no one can take for granted the world he lives in, the things he treasures, or the values and principles that seem to him so obvious.

Those of us who have been spared the horrors in which our age specializes, who have never suffered total war, slave-labor camp or police terror, not only owe thanks; we owe charity and compassion.  


But ours is also a time of new vision and greatness, of opportunity and challenge, to everyone in his daily life, as a person and as a citizen.

It is a time in which everyone is an understudy to the leading role in the drama of human destiny.

Everyone must be ready to take over alone and without notice, and show himself saint or hero, villain or coward.

On this stage the great roles are not written in the iambic pentameter or the Alexandrine of the heroic theater.

They are prosaic—played out in one’s daily life, in one’s work, in one’s citizenship, in one’s compassion or lack of it, in one’s courage to stick to an unpopular principle, and in one’s refusal to sanction man’s inhumanity to man in an age of cruelty and moral numbness.  


In a time of change and challenge, new vision and new danger, new frontiers and permanent crisis, suffering and achievement, in a time of overlap such as ours, the individual is both all-powerless and all-powerful.

He is powerless, however exalted his station, if he believes that he can impose his will, that he can command the tides of history.

He is all-powerful, no matter how lowly, if he knows himself to be responsible.

 

line

 

Up to Poverty

The Frontier of Development

“Nothing ever changes here,” said the manager of the Bangkok branch of a large American manufacturing company to the young man who had just come out from the Chicago head office to make a study of the changes in Far Eastern markets.

“And nothing ever will change here,” he continued; “these people have no initiative, no ambition, no vision.

All this pushing of new products, new methods and new ideas from Chicago is just plain foolishness.”  


The two were sitting in a restaurant in one of the city’s main streets; and the young man was idly looking out at the noisy throng of cars, buses, trucks, motorcycles and bicycles—the traffic jam that characterizes all cities in the Free World today in sharp contrast to the regimented emptiness of city streets in Communist countries.

The branch manager—an elderly man who had spent most of his adult life working for American companies in the Far East—went on with his theme of the changeless, shiftless East.

But the young man hardly heard him; he watched the traffic.

Suddenly he turned his head and asked: “And how are you getting your goods to the customer today?”  


“About 90 per cent by truck, the rest by motor launch; we have the most up-to-date delivery system in the city,” was the immediate answer.  


“And how did you move them twenty years ago when you first came to Bangkok?” the young man continued.  


“Oh, mostly on bamboo poles carried on coolies’ backs,” was the answer.  


“Yet you then also had the most up-to-date delivery system in the city, I imagine,” the young man murmured.  


This story, with slight variations, fits every city in the so-called underdeveloped countries: Leopoldville in the Belgian Congo or Salisbury in Rhodesia; Belém at the mouth of the Amazon, La Paz high up on the Andean Plateau, or Fairbanks, Alaska, at the rim of the frozen Arctic; Konya in Central Anatolia; Beirut in Lebanon, Meshed in Persia, Baghdad, Bombay, Rangoon or Gauguin’s Tahiti.

It might have to be changed before it would fit in the Communist world.

But there too the overnight leap has been made from Abraham’s time into the machine age, from the storyteller under the banyan tree to the radio, from the wooden hoe to the fifty-ton drop forge in the steel mill.

radar-differences-pict-400

And yet the real change is not physical; it is not trucks and radios and machine tools.

It is not even in the way people’s lives have been altered: the sudden transformation of the Peruvian Indian living in the pre-Inca Stone Age into a skilled machinist in an automated paper mill; or the sudden transformation of the Mongolian nomadic herdsman into a bookkeeper.  


The real change is in vision, beliefs and expectations.  


For the first time in man’s history the whole world is united and unified.

This may seem a strange statement in view of the conflicts and threats of suicidal war that scream at us from every headline.

But despite the reality and danger of conflict, mankind today shares the same vision, the same goal and the same hope; it even believes in the same tools.  


This vision might, in gross oversimplification, be called economic development.

It is the belief that man can improve his economic lot through systematic, purposeful and directed effort—individually as well as for an entire society.

It is the belief that we have at our disposal the technological, the conceptual and the social tools to enable man to raise himself, through his own efforts, at least to the level that we in the West would consider poverty, but which for most of our world would be almost unbelievable luxury.

Management and Economic Development

This vision is the important, the central fact.

It is a vision not of individual wealth, but of a productive society.

It is a vision of freedom from the slavery to want and the bondage to material destitution in which the human race has always existed.

The aim is not luxury.

It is a level just above mere material subsistence, where man is no longer controlled by starvation and at the mercy of every cloudburst, hailstorm or drought.

The promise is that one’s children will not forever be forced to go to work as mere infants to contribute to the meager subsistence of the family, but that they will have a chance to learn and to develop.

It is the hope that man will not forever be caught in the quest for the next meal, but will be able to put material things in their proper, subordinate place as means to higher human ends.  


This to be sure is a material vision.

But the ends are not material fulfillment for the individual but material independence for individual and society alike.

What impresses the outside world about the United States today is not how our rich men live—the world has seen riches before, and on a larger and more ostentatious scale.

What impresses the outside world is how the poor of this country live.  


Up to Poverty” is the proper slogan for the great worldwide vision and improvement.

The Agents of Revolution

“I can always tell an Indian who has driven a truck or a tractor,” the old, experienced manager of a big sugar estate in South America said to me once.

“He stands straight and talks back at me.”

The manager was a Spaniard, proud of his Castilian speech and his pure lineage.

He had always been kind to the Indian field hands.

But he had always looked down on them as an inferior race, had treated them with the care and affection a good husbandman gives to his horses, had, at best, thought of them as irresponsible children.

“But now,” he said, “we must realize that, in another twenty years, one of them will have to be able to take my place and do my job.

For the internal combustive engine is doing what neither Spanish Crown nor Catholic Church could do.

It is making a man out of the Indian.”  


Similarly, in this country, it was the automobile that gave momentum to the Negro’s drive toward racial equality.

“We had no troubles until the depression years when the Negroes first started to have cars,” said a Southern newspaper editor, himself of the old school and bitterly opposed to racial integration.

“White folks around here blame the New Deal, the government in Washington, Northern agitators or education.

They are all wrong.

Segregation was dead when the first Negro found out that a white man better get out of the way of an old jalopy even though a colored man be at the wheel.

Up till then he accepted inferiority no matter what his leaders told him.

After he’d made the first white man wait for him before crossing the road, he knew he wasn’t inferior.”  


And a petroleum geologist adds to this: “The jeep means the end of the Bedouin tribe.

It can go where no camel can go.

There is no longer any hiding out for the nomad subject to no law but his tribal code, obedient to no command but that of his tribal sheik.

When I first came to Arabia, in the thirties, we cocked our rifles when we ran into Bedouin tribesmen.

Now we drive over and ask them whether we can listen to the news on the battery radio that the lead camel carries.”  


The agents of the revolution that has created the vision of economic development are the new tools of communication, the new agents of physical and psychological mobility.

There is the radio which brings the whole world with all its ideas, its excitement, its dreams, into the most remote hamlet.

The battery radio on the Bedouin’s lead camel may well be the best symbol of this revolution.

There is the dirt road which for the first time in history makes it possible for goods and ideas to reach the isolated villages—and for people to leave life in isolation and to move to the city with its companionship, its lights, its jobs, its schools.

And then there is the truck, the jeep, the old jalopy fitted out with a wooden body to serve as a bus, and increasingly the plane, destroying distance and fear of the unknown, creating mobility, knowledge and desire.  


These new tools are changing the very meaning of “economic necessities.”

Economists maintain that economic development starts with subsistence needs: food, clothing and shelter.

As people shift from the peasant’s natural economy to the money economy of the city, they should thereby create a constantly growing demand for, say, cheap textiles.

Luxuries supposedly come much later.

This, at least, is what the Industrial Revolution did in Western countries; when it first began, the textile industry was the growth industry.

To a large extent the Point Four program of the United States has been based on this axiom of the economists.  


But it does not work out that way in the growth countries of today.

It is indeed amazing how well dressed the urban masses are in the burgeoning cities of these countries.

The shopgirls may live in miserable rat-infested shacks.

But they wear the same patterns one sees in Milan or Milwaukee.

The styles and patterns Lancashire (or its imitators in Japan and India) used to make for the Indian or the South African trade cannot be sold to those countries today, not even at bargain prices.

Yet they do not buy more clothing.

I know of half a dozen large cities in the growth countries where textile sales have actually fallen these last ten years, despite doubling of the population and boom-time prosperity.

The same goes for other “essentials” of subsistence living such as food and even housing.  


The goods and services for which the demand increases disproportionately fast are such things as radios and household appliances, gasoline and electric power.

The greatest increase in demand is for schools for the children.

And the dream of every peasant who moves into the city is to own a car, however ramshackle, or at least a motor scooter, or at the very least a bicycle.  


These are, in truth, the real consumer necessities in today’s economic development.

They symbolize its vision: a break through the age-old walls of isolation, a new, wider horizon, power over physical forces instead of enslavement to them, and opportunities for the children.  


Indeed these new necessities show that economics itself is assuming a new meaning.

Economists have long emphasized that the true measure of economic advance is not material—that is, a higher standard of living—but human: increasing freedom to choose and to act.

In the old developed countries of the West, economic development did not contribute such noneconomic, human values to large masses until fairly late in the process.

At first it contributed the old necessities, subsistence goods which provided material satisfaction for material wants.

In the development countries of today, however, the emphasis right from the start has been on creating alternatives of choice and freedom.

The means, to be sure, are material.

But the new economic necessities are the keys to doors that lead out of immemorial bondage in isolation, want and ignorance to freedom of movement, freedom of knowledge, freedom of choice and opportunity.

The Promise and the Danger

The full measure of the power of industrial society is its ability to stir the imagination.

Even in the remote mountain villages of Tibet or the Andes, the promise of economic development possesses man with the force almost of a Messianic vision.

He may not be able to realize the vision; but that he can believe it attainable releases tremendous energies.  


But this vision also creates a new problem: international economic inequality.

It creates a new danger: international and interracial class war between the underdeveloped poor countries and the developed rich.  


We, on the North American Continent, including our Canadian friends and neighbors, are a mere 10 per cent of the world’s population.

But we have about 75 per cent of the world’s income.

By contrast, the 75 per cent of the world population whose income is below $125 per person a year receives altogether perhaps no more than 10 per cent of the world’s income.  


The twenty largest underdeveloped countries produce well over half of the Free World’s industrial raw materials.

But they themselves consume less than 5 per cent of what they produce.

All of them excepting Brazil are “colored.”  


The inequality is increasing.

Income per person in the fifteen developed countries with the highest standard of living (all “white” except for Japan) was in 1938, on average, seven times the income per person in the twenty largest underdeveloped countries.

By 1955 this disparity had widened to a ratio of eight to one.

Yet, there had been large-scale wartime destruction in major developed countries and an unprecedented raw-materials boom in most of the underdeveloped ones.

This international inequality of income contrasts sharply with internal high equality of income in the developed countries, especially in ours where we are in the process of proving that an industrial society does not have to live in extreme tension between the few very rich and the many very poor.

What used to be national inequality and economic tension is now rapidly becoming international and unfortunately also interracial inequality and tension.  


We are engaged today in a race between the promise of economic development and the threat of international worldwide class war.

Economic development is the opportunity of this age.

Class war is the danger.

The two are the essential economic realities of this industrial age of ours.

Whether we shall realize the opportunity or succumb to the danger will not only decide the economic future of the world—it may largely decide its spiritual, its intellectual, its political and its social future.

Is Economic Development Possible?

This new situation poses the question: Is economic development possible?

Or is it a mirage?  


There are many reasons for wondering.

Anyone looking for scientific proof of a trend toward economic development would search in vain.

During the last fifty years the majority of mankind has hardly improved its lot; in many parts of the world, for instance in China or in India, there may actually have been deterioration.

In the least developed rural areas, where most of the “colored” races live, population is growing so much faster than the economy that there is danger of economic collapse.  


Economic development is seriously hampered by all kinds of economic superstitions and delusions that are taken for gospel truth in most of the world today (including our own country).

Perhaps most dangerous is the confusion between equality of opportunity and equality of income and rewards.

The first is a dynamo of economic development.

The second is deadly poison in the early stages of development.

Soviet Russia has shown this most convincingly; but few people understand the lesson.  


Yet, though it is neither easy nor automatic, economic development is possible.  


The most visible evidence that it is not an impractical dream is Soviet Russia.

This is, however, a misleading example, since the Soviet Union started out at a much higher economic level than most of the underdeveloped countries of the world.

The economic level of European Russia in 1913 was almost as high as that of northern Italy.

Soviet Russia also started out with plenty of open, empty space.

Indeed, up till World War II the Soviet Union was a good example of mis-development.  


The economic development of Latin-American countries, especially of Mexico, Brazil and Colombia, in the last twenty-five years is more impressive evidence that economic development is feasible.

Perhaps even more meaningful are Turkey and Puerto Rico—two areas with singularly unfavorable natural conditions for economic development, in which, nevertheless, real progress has been made.  


But the best example is the oldest: Japan.

A century ago Japan was a feudal anarchy; she was one of the poorest and most backward of all economies—and at the same time already densely populated.

Within forty years she had transformed herself into a modern economy with tremendous growth potential.

She did, apparently instinctively, all the things which we now know to be essential to rapid economic development.

As a result the progress of Japan during the fifty years up to World War I was faster than anything the Soviet Union has ever been able to achieve.

In many ways therefore it is Japan, the Japan of the Meji Revolution, that should serve as our model.


Today, for the first time, we have a tested theory to describe what went on in Japan a century ago.

Since the end of World War II, economic development has not only become a major goal of national and international policy but its study has become central to economic theory.  


The understanding of economic development, and the new ability it gives us, rest on the new world-view.

We can understand economic development because we see it as a purposeful process, as a pattern rather than as a mechanism.

We can organize economic development because of our concept of innovation.

Economic development does not come about by evolutionary imitation of the experience of the developed countries.

It does not go from mercantilism to “putting-out” system to steam-driven machinery and so on, or from making necessities by hand to making the same necessities by machine.

It leap-frogs from primitive to developed economy.

The new organization is the engine that powers this economic leap.

The ability to organize men for skill and knowledge is the basic resource of economic development, and conversely the lack of men capable of doing this, both as professional specialists and as managers, is its greatest obstacle.

It is not, however, the only obstacle.

Thanks to our new logic of innovation, we can predict what various other difficulties will be.

 

line

 

The New Pluralism (1957)

The exclusive monopoly of government on organized institutional power in society has been so seriously undermined as, to be in a state of near-collapse.

The agent of this collapse is our new power to organize.

It is rapidly creating new autonomous power centers within the body politic.  


In an industrial economy the individual is, by and large, productive only insofar as he has access to an organized institution of production and distribution, the enterprise.

By himself, the individual in an industrial system can work, but he cannot produce.

 

The Three Stonecutters

 

Only the institutional system organized for performance and survival beyond the lifetime, and independent of, any one individual is capable of production.  


This is not the result of a sinister plot.

Nor is there any alternative if we want industrial production and its fruits.

The Alternative to Tyranny

What has caused this development is precisely the factor that is responsible for our industrial advance: the modern ability to organize men of high skill, knowledge and judgment for joint work and performance.

 

sidebar

 

sound-players-pict-no-reflect-400

sound players

#ewtl Operacy — the thinking that goes into doing …

evidence-wall-and-time-line-pict-600

From Knowledge to KnowledgeS ::: Knowledge and Technology #pdf

Information challenges ::: #41 Strategic decisions ↑ ::: Six Thinking Hats

 

The Alternative to Tyranny

 

Management and the World’s Work

 

main brainroad continues

 

This both makes possible and requires a scale of operation beyond the ability of any single man to direct, let alone to do.

It requires such a variety of skills, knowledges and temperaments as can be supplied only by a large group of different people in organized, permanent effort.

It requires the commitment of present resources to a futurity of such length as to be beyond the working life of any individual.

It requires capital far beyond the means of any man, were he even a modern Croesus.

Above all, it requires managing, that is systematic planning, organizing, integrating and measuring of the efforts and work of highly skilled and highly educated people which can be done only by an organized and disciplined body of men.  


generating-station-on-the-la-grande-river-600

Employees at Hydro Quebec worked on a turbine
deep underground at the Robert Bourassa generating station
on the La Grande River in northern Quebec.

Employees at Hydro Quebec worked on a turbine deep underground at the Robert Bourassa generating station on the La Grande River in northern Quebec.

 

It requires a power center, partial in its purposes, to be sure, but largely autonomous.  


As a result, new institutional power centers have shot up like Topsy.

To take our own country as an example: Fifty years ago the federal government was a shadow of its present self.

It spent less in a year than it now spends in a day.

All its civilian employees could have been housed comfortably in one of the Washington buildings now occupied—and overcrowded—by one of the smaller agencies.

The state governments were, as a rule, one-man shows.

And the job of being state governor, while honorific, was so little burdensome that in some of the sparsely settled states the incumbent could still keep in touch with his private law practice.  


But—and it is a big “but”—there was no other institutional organization of social or economic power.

There were a few very rich men, a Morgan or a Rockefeller, who had great personal power and influence.

There were a few “trusts”; but even though they so badly frightened our grandfathers, the largest of them were so small, whether in assets, in sales or in number of employees, that they would go unmentioned in any list of “five hundred largest corporations” today.

Only a few railroads and telegraph companies were then so large that we would today consider them “big business”; and they were already being brought under effective governmental regulation.

 

evidence-wall-and-time-line-pict-600

harvest and implement

 

economic-structure-and-calendar-pict-600

harvest and implement

 

Otherwise, there was nothing.

Big business, the labor unions, national farmers’ organizations, the National Association of Manufacturers, the American Medical Association, the National Education Association, all these were still to come.  


The world of the American citizen in those days looked very much like the Kansas prairie.

family-old-pict-500

… and at that time ↓, unimagined futureS seemed unthinkable …

nyc-street-600t

A Century of Social Transformation

Except for one hill, the individual citizen was the tallest thing as far as the eye could see.

And even this hill, the federal government, while it looked imposing, was only a few hundred feet high.  


Today the power charge of our society has been built up as it has never been before.

Instead of the Kansas prairie, the citizen has the Himalayas around him.

Here are the towering institutional peaks of big business, there the rugged and almost sheer cliffs of organized labor closing off access to trades, crafts and jobs to all but the dues-paying members.

The farmers are dominated by national farm organizations, medicine by the American Medical Association, and so on.

 

About un-centralizing in
Adventures of a Bystander and

The need for theory in
The Age of Discontinuity:
Guidelines To Our Changing Society


Part of THE memo

 

Even religious life, almost without power charge in the America of fifty years ago, is today increasingly organized in strong national institutions which speak for the individual denominations, lobby before Congress and conduct their own campaigns.  


Within the government itself the administrative bureaucracy and the armed forces have largely become organized—though not yet autonomous—institutional power centers.  


Of course, the federal government too has grown and expanded in size as well as power.

It is clearly the Everest amongst the Himalayan peaks.

But in relation to the total power charge of society as expressed by the other new institutions, the federal government may well have become less, rather than more, powerful.

Certainly its power monopoly has been broken.  


The development of the new power centers within society may have gone furthest and fastest in this country.

 

evidence wall and timeline larger

evidence-wall-and-time-line-pict-600

 

But the growth itself is not specifically American; it is the result of the emergence of modern industry.

Even in Soviet Russia, Stalin, while absolute despot, could only maintain his personal power by playing against each other the major power centers of Communist party bureaucracy, Army, Secret Police and industrial management.

Since his death there has been an increasing power play between them, making and breaking governments.

Even behind the facade of “monolithic” Communism, the new institutional powers have therefore become the actual political reality.

Even there, the exclusive monopoly of organized institutional power, which had been one of the foundations of modern government, has been undermined.

 

Peter Drucker — political / social ecologist

Description is not #perception

Post-Capitalist Society

Data, Information, Knowledge

The Emerging Knowledge Society

The Manager and the Moron

The responsibility based organization

 


 

The New Metropolis

The emergent industrial society has had another major impact on the foundations of government: It erodes local government.

It creates a new social community: the metropolis.

And we do not know how to govern it. …

 

line

 

The Vanishing East

 

evidence wall and timeline larger

evidence-wall-and-time-line-pict-600

Career time view

The MEMO they don’t want you to see

 

East is East and West is ‘West,

And never the twain shall meet.

 

So sang Kipling, laureate of empire at its high noon.

Millions of people who never have heard his name know these lines.

Many still accept them as folk wisdom.  


It is always rash to say “never” to the future.

Kipling has been dead only twenty-five years.

But today “the twain have met”—in one chaotic, anarchic, explosive but common world disorder and world civilization.

“East” and “West” have almost become mere geographic directions again

rather than meaningful terms of politics, civilization and culture,

“Commonwealth” has succeeded “Empire”;

and at the Commonwealth meetings in the last ten years, the dominant figure has been Nehru, the complete East-Westerner: fiery Indian nationalist and master of English prose, high-caste, proud Brahman and agnostic Fabian Socialist, idol of the Indian villagers and fervent apostle of heavy industry.  


Yet Kipling was right—though not in the way he intended to be.

His West and his East have indeed not met:

the nineteenth-century West of the European power system,

and the mysterious East

of tribal village and Peacock Throne,

of peasant following the bullock behind the wooden plow, and

of Confucian mandarin learning ancient texts by rote, have not met.  


Both have disappeared.

 

---***---

 

Only fifty years ago the European power system was still substantially what it had been ever since the end of Europe’s Religious Wars.

The non-European great powers—Japan and the United States—were not accepted into full membership until World War I.

For 250 years all great powers had been European; and all but Russia had already been members when the Westphalian Peace Treaties of 1648 first established the European power system.  


It was the stablest power system the world had seen since the days of Caesar Augustus; and it became the most powerful.

From 1700 on, it had been taken for granted that political sovereignty or economic control over entire countries with millions of inhabitants anywhere in the world could be bestowed or transferred by treaty between European great powers.

In fact, the only successful challenges came from the United States, itself European by race and culture (in the Monroe Doctrine of 1823, and in John Hay’s Open-Door Policy of 1902 which prevented the partitioning of China among the great European powers).  


Just a little over seventy years ago nobody thought it extraordinary that a minor European potentate, the King of the Belgians, was given, largely in recognition of his family connections, personal ownership of one fourth of the whole Continent of Africa.

Twenty years later he was allowed as a matter of course to dispose of this entire Congo territory with all its inhabitants by personal last will and testament.

Even the First World War hardly seemed to dent the European power system.

The victors divided among themselves the non-European possessions of the defeated in Asia, Africa and Oceania, with out even a show of concern for the wishes of the inhabitants.  


As late as the mid-twenties there was only one territory on the whole inhabitable globe that was not controlled by Europeans or their descendants: Japan.

To be sure, there were seven other non-European countries that were considered sovereign and independent: China, Siam, Afghanistan, Persia, Ethiopia, Liberia and Haiti.

But of these, Liberia and Haiti were wards of the United States.

Siam, Afghanistan and Ethiopia were “buffer states” between territories of great powers and maintained by them deliberately for that purpose.

Persia, while officially sovereign, had actually been divided into spheres of influence by Great Britain and Russia.

China, the largest, was saved from a similar fate only by United States intervention; even so China’s economic life and political institutions were run by Europeans who controlled courts and universities, ports, transportation, taxes and customs service, communications and industries.  


Sometimes the buffoons of history tell us more than the tragic actors.

Such a buffoon was the retired British Army colonel who around 1920 claimed to have discovered the “Secret of the Great Pyramid”: The British were really the Lost Tribe of Israel, and therefore the rightful heirs forever to world domination.

As proof he offered—quite seriously—that the Lord had promised Israel the land of milk and honey; and did not the British control the world’s petroleum and the world’s rubber?

Of course he was a madman; but thousands of people in Great Britain, the Dominions and the United States took his ravings seriously — the movement was still going strong in rural Canada around 1940.  


Even World War II, only a decade ago, was fought under the spell of the European power system.

The pivotal decision in World War II was to throw the major energies of the United States into the European theater of war rather than into the Pacific.

That this was both difficult and risky was well understood.

The people who made the decision in the United States knew that it might well mean the loss of China.

The people who urged it in Great Britain saw that it might well mean the end of British rule in India.

Yet it was inescapable at the time.  


It was no longer correct, as President Roosevelt believed—in what was surely a major blunder—that world peace could be established by restoring the pre-1914 Concert of Europe, that is by ridding Europe of the danger of German aggression.

But as late as 1943 or 1944, a world war could still only be won-or lost—as a European war.  


One might even say that the first few years after World War II remained under the constellation of the European power system.

For the traditional European countries it was a decade of weakness and power shrinkage.

But the United States’s military and economic hegemony during that decade filled the resulting vacuum.

The situation could not last—hegemony never does.

It was a delusion of Western, and especially of American, policy that it could endure or even that it should endure.

But certainly in these first postwar years, during which the United States had a monopoly on atomic weapons combined with international economic predominance, the lineaments of the old Western-controlled world were still discernible.  


By now they have all but disappeared.

Japan’s occupation of the European colonies in the Far East, Indian independence, the victory of Communism in China, the Korean War, the Suez debacle—each of these was another landslide burying the ruins of the European power system and creating a new world landscape.

The final step would be European unification—both an acknowledgment of the end of the old system of European power balance and perhaps the first major step toward a new stability and order.  


The Cold War could still be lost in Europe by either side.  


The loss to Communism of Germany, France or Italy would be a severe blow to the Free World, and one from which it might not be able to recover.

Similarly, the loss of the European satellites would be a heavy blow to Communism.  


But the Cold War can no longer be won in Europe.

It can only be won in the non-European world, the countries of Asia and Africa, which only yesterday were mere pawns in the European power game.

Our side can win only if non-European peoples exercising their own independent decisions, and acting through their own governments, choose for themselves the values and ways of the Free World.  


The European power system is gone so completely that the currently accepted view of the world conflict as one between two Western and white superpowers, the United States and Russia, may soon be obsolete.

The ability of the Free World to prevail—perhaps to survive—may well hinge on the ability of the new and emphatically non-European Republic of India to maintain a free government and to develop an expanding economy and a stable society.

It is even imaginable that, twenty years hence, the threat of a new, and even less European, superpower, China—with a population of a billion people and growing industrial production—might force into close alliance the United States, Western Europe and Russia, despite their fundamental differences in principles, values and beliefs.

 

stages-simple-horizons-pict-t

 

economic-structure-and-calendar-pict-600

larger composite view ↑ ::: Economic & content and structure ::: Adoption rates: one & two

Entrepreneurship vs. traditional economics

 

time-line-and-adoption-rates-pict-t-600

 

Success or Failure of the West?

The European power system died of its own success.

Every one of the forces that destroyed it was of Western origin, generated by the West and propagated by it.

Nationalism is the West’s very own enfant terrible.

The campaign against colonialism only repeats the arguments and slogans of generations of European and American liberals.

Everywhere it is being led by men trained and educated in the West, and Western in their thinking, their arguments, their principles.

In the thirties it was said that only an honors degree from Oxford or Cambridge qualified an Indian to be jailed for resistance to British rule.

Today this applies, with variations, to all the remaining colonial areas of the Western powers.

Moscow-trained Communists are similarly the most likely leaders of resistance to the new Russian colonialism in the satellite countries.

And, of course, Communism is entirely Western—a heresy, to be sure, but one that could only have grown on Western soil and out of Western heritage.  


The world order that will succeed the European power system might well be anti-Western; but it will quite definitely not be un-Western.

Every single one of the new countries in the world today—including those that have not yet shaken off colonial status—sees its goal in its transformation into a Western state, economy and society, and sees the means to achieve this goal in the theories, institutions, sciences, technologies and tools the West has developed.

---***---

Kipling and his generation could hardly have foreseen this development.  


To them it appeared obvious that the non-Western peoples would reject the institutions, ideas and principles of the West.

At the time this was a reasonable assumption.  


Take for example the American Negro.

Of all non-European peoples anywhere, he has been most completely divorced from any native culture of his own.

He has had the longest and most complete exposure to a purely Western culture and tradition.

Yet when the original promise of Booker T. Washington’s “separate but equal” proved an illusion around World War I, the first reaction of the American Negro was to turn anti-Western—to change the slogan, so to speak, to “separate but really separate.”

Thirty years ago the movements with the greatest mass appeal among this largest non-European group in the United States were those that, like Marcus Garvey’s, repudiated the values, institutions and customs of the white world.

They proposed instead to develop a strictly separate American Negro culture on its own African foundation, and a community strictly apart from, and outside that of, the white man.  


Today nothing is left of these movements.

When the South African Boer talks about the same idea under the name of “apartheid,” he is denounced as a disgrace and a danger by people of good will everywhere.

Only a generation ago, however, this seemed the forward-looking, progressive position.

As late as 1935 international Communism, after long and careful deliberation, adopted it in a calculated bid to capture the allegiance of the American Negro.

Organizations that then stood for Negro emancipation and equality within white society, such as the National Association for the Advancement of the Colored People (NAACP), were denounced as “timid,” “conservative” and “appeasers.”  


Western ideals and institutions proved too powerful not only for Marcus Garvey’s dream but for any attempt to develop new, independent, non-European communities on their own nonEuropean foundations.

Regardless of the age and refinement of their own tradition, all the nonEuropean peoples today have, like the American Negro, accepted that neither “separate but equal” nor “separate but separate” are the answer.

Instead they acknowledge that to be equal with the West and with one another they must themselves be Western.  


The second assumption of Kipling’s generation has also been disproven: that non-European peoples are incapable of acquiring the ways of the West, and especially of acquiring proficiency in Western industrial and military technology.  


At the beginning of World War II, people thought the Japanese constitutionally incapable of flying modern aircraft—“something to do with their eyes,” they said.

We soon found out that Japanese fighter pilots were second to none.

Later, during the early stages of the Korean War, a good many high-ranking, professional soldiers believed equally seriously that the Chinese soldier could not stand up under fire or would not fight in the dark.

The hoary superstition that the Hindu or the Chinese will not make an efficient industrial worker—the one because of caste, the other because he is “too individualistic”—is still around, though it was completely disprove” by actual experience in both countries a century ago.  


Fifty years ago the borderlands of the North Atlantic had a virtual monopoly on industrial and military technology, knowledge and skills.

To assume a continuation of this monopoly was perhaps not unreasonable at the time.

Technology is, after all, not something by itself, but the child of values, cultural traditions and historical development, all of which were distinctly Western, Yet—beginning with Japan industrial and military technology has proven to be far easier of acquisition by non-Western people than Western political or social beliefs and institutions.

All over the world, nonWestern peoples are rapidly industrializing and rapidly building Western-style armed forces.

The technological monopoly of the North Atlantic countries has been broken for good.

The Failure of the East

The European power system has collapsed; but at the same time, the East has vanished.  


This may seem paradoxical in view of the strong influence of, and high interest in, Eastern (or rather non-Western) ideas in the West today.

It began with Gauguin and, a little later, with the impact of primitive Negro sculpture on modern art.

It led to the emergence of jazz as a major musical influence.

At the same time Gandhi became a powerful influence on Western liberalism and pacifism.

Today there is the great interest in the cultures of that non-Western Westerner, the American Indian, and in his ancient civilizations in Central America and in the Andes.  


And there is the influence of Japan on American art, architecture and design, and the interest in that most Eastern of metaphysics, Zen-Buddhism, with its strong affinities to our own new view of the universe.  


More and more historians stress that “world history” is not simply “European history” writ larger.

Thus we now increasingly see ancient Greece as one of the great archaic civilizations of the Orient rather than as a Western civilization all by itself.  


It is true that the West has lost its old certainty of superiority and with it its old provincialism.

But it is also true—and much more important—that no viable society today can be built on nonWestern foundations.

---***---

This is not speculation.

It is experience.

In the three oldest, most advanced and richest nonWestern cultures—Japan, China and India—the attempt has been made to base a viable society on inherited, non-Western foundations—and in all three it has failed.  


Modern Japan grew out of an extraordinary effort to create on the spiritual and social foundations of Japan’s own heritage a society capable of survival in the modern world.

The aim was to preserve the substance of Japan through adoption of the forms and tools of the West.  


There has rarely been an abler, more dedicated or more clear-headed generation than the men who transformed, in thirty or forty years, the stagnant, frozen and demoralized Japan of the last Shoguns, the Japan of 1857, into the dynamic, organized and proud Japanese Empire of 1900.

Insofar as they Westernized the country they were a complete success.

The Japan of 1857 could not protect its inland ports against a single foreign gunboat.

Fifty years later Japan could decisively defeat both the army and the navy of imperial Russia.

In 1857 Japan was almost totally illiterate.

Fifty years later its literacy rate compared favorably with many European countries; and she had as large a proportion of her young people in secondary schools and universities as had Germany.

The Japan of 1857 was one of the most backward and poverty-stricken economies in the world.

Fifty years later she had the highest per capita income among all non-Western countries, was virtually self-sufficient in heavy industry and could compete on the world markets.  


Indeed to this day, late nineteenth-century Japan is the outstanding example of the rapid economic development of an underdeveloped country.

Her achievement was greater, her growth faster, than that of Soviet Russia since 1917.

She had to overcome the obstacles of limited raw materials and of heavy overpopulation without empty virgin lands.

Yet she developed without tyranny and terror, without concentration camps and purges.  


But the attempt to build modern Japan on Japanese cultural, social and political foundations was a failure.

It created strains and tensions that brought about the suicidal flight from self-control and sanity of the next generation, that of the twenties and thirties.

When the collapse into defeat and humiliation came, it was not the Western forms and tools that disappeared, but any attempt to preserve a non-Western substance.

Today’s Japan stands or falls with the success of root-and-branch Westernization.  


In Japan the attempt to build a viable society on nonWestern foundations was essentially mechanistic—to join together elements of East and West.

In China—the oldest, the proudest and the most adaptable civilization—Dr. Sun Yat-sen tried instead to distill out of China’s own tradition guiding principles for her self-renewal as a modern society.

The revolutionary impact of his teaching, its ability to loosen the bonds of the old regime and to inspire young people with a passionate desire for something new, can hardly be over estimated.

Nor should the achievements of “Young China” between 1912 and 1930 be underestimated.  


Still the attempt failed.

What would have happened to Dr. Sun Yat-sen’s China had there been no Japanese invasion can never be proven.

But by 1930 basic weaknesses had already appeared, and it was by then clear that Sun Yat-sen’s attempt could not revive the old, rural China, around which his whole doctrine had been built.

The Chinese Communists repudiated this old China with its traditional values and beliefs.

They demanded instead that peasant China be made over in a new, Western, though Communist image.

And with this they denounced also any attempt to preserve China’s own traditions or to build on them.

Mao Tse-tung may himself write Chinese poetry in classic ideograms; but his regime has begun to introduce a Latin alphabet which is to be taught exclusively in the future, and which aims at making the classic writings a dead language accessible only to scholars.  


The most significant failure is probably Gandhi’s in India.

Unlike the Japanese and unlike Sun Yat-sen, Gandhi was not content with merging East and West.

He aimed at building on the foundations of the spirit a better, purer, stronger society that could be model and inspiration to East and West alike.  


Here clearly was the greatest vision, the deepest understanding.

Here also was a very great man, a saint and a shrewd political leader.

His impact on the people of India was probably greater than that of any other man since the Prince Buddha 2,500 years ago.

Not only the educated but the masses, in the hopeless isolation of their sun-baked mud hovels, caught the vision and were moved by it.

Even untouchability and landlordism, which neither force nor reason had ever been able to weaken, showed signs of melting under his moral fervor.  


British rule crumpled before Gandhi.

Independent India is above all his achievement.

Every Indian leader today claims to be his disciple—and most actually are.

Even the Indian Communists pay lip service to his greatness.

Yet only ten years after his death, there is little left of his social, political or economic gospel.

India today sees her salvation in rapid industrialization, in steel mills, fertilizer plants, power dams and truck transportation—rather than in the self-denying, austere anti-industrialism of Gandhi’s spinning wheel.

A completely Western army, rather than nonviolent resistance, is her mainstay in international affairs.  


The present Indian government, though composed of Gandhi’s closest associates, seems singularly unimpressed by the power of nonviolent resistance such as threw the British into complete confusion.

There have been many more “incidents,” in which police and army were ordered to fire on demonstrators in the first ten years of Indian independence than in the last ten years of British rule.

The present Indian government has given in only to violent rioting, not once—as the British so often did—to moral force.

And instead of Gandhi’s spiritual foundation, the present rulers base their ideas of society, economy and government on purely Western and purely secular ideas, such as, in Nehru’s case, English Fabian Socialism of 1919 vintage.

The only exceptions are the orthodox Hindu sectarians—but their ideal is to purge India of all innovations whether Gandhian or Western.  


I am convinced of Gandhi’s lasting impact—unless, indeed, independent India collapses into anarchy, civil war, totalitarianism, or before a new conquest by a foreign invader.

But it is unlikely that there will ever be an attempt to realize Gandhi’s society, that post-modern dream that was to be more truly a fulfillment of the basic values of the West than any Western country has ever been, and which yet was to rest on the non-Western foundations of India’s own spiritual heritage.

That attempt—despite its nobility and popular appeal—has failed.

---***---

Where Kipling’s generation erred was in their belief that the East had such power, such deep, rock-bottom strength, that it would resist the corroding acid of Western ideas, Western institutions, Western technology and Western goods.  


To the best of the West’s representatives in the non-Western world this resistance was precisely its attraction.

The great colonials—Gordon in China, Curzon in India, Lyautey in Morocco, Lugard in Nigeria, Lawrence in Arabia, Kipling himself—were all at odds with their own West, were strangers, rebels or misfits at home.

They romanticized the East, they saw it as their mission to build it up and protect it against the West—Curzon’s fantastic attempt to recreate the India of the Mogul Empire in the “Great Durbar” of 1906 was perhaps the most spectacular example, but by no means an isolated one.

This explains their incredible inability to see, let alone to understand, the impact and importance of the Western-trained, Westernized lawyer, teacher, journalist or politician.

To the very end the Western colonial administrators persisted in the delusion that these people were “scum,” that they had no influence at all on the “masses,” were indeed actually repudiated by them.  


In a most perceptive book written by a former colonial about European rule in the East—Philip Woodruff’s The Men Who Ruled India—this is still a recurrent theme.

Yet the book was written in 1953, six years after the “Westernized troublemakers” had forced the last Union Jack in India to be struck.

A similar delusion underlies French policy in North Africa.

It determines much of American policy in the Arab world and explains our worst mistakes there.  


The heritage and values of non-Western society will not be lost forever.

Such deep traditions of old and advanced cultures cannot remain forever powerless, inert and ineffectual.

But they will again become a living force only if the nonWestern countries succeed in building viable societies on Western foundations: Western values and institutions; Western education, economics and technology; Western means of mass communication and mass organization.

This is the lesson the non-Western countries themselves have learned—from Nehru in India and Mao in China to Nasser and Bourguiba in the Arab countries and Dr. Nkrumah in the Gold Coast.  


These men do not agree among themselves on values and institutions.

They mean quite different things when they say “free government.”

But their differences are those of Westerners, the differences between the free West and the totalitarians; they all believe in the strong, central, professional government of the modern West.

They do not agree on the principles of economic organization; but they all accept industrialization and organized large-scale enterprise, economic welfare and advancement as major goals of human society.

They may not believe in “freedom of speech” or “freedom of thought”; but they all accept and exploit the printing press and the mass media of communication and propaganda.

And they all accept—indeed they all worship—education in the Western sense and its product, the professional lawyer, doctor, scientist, bureaucrat or technologist.

Can the West and the New East Meet?

This is a highly unfashionable question to ask today.

Anyone who raises it is certain to be called a “reactionary,” at Oxford or Harvard, in New Delhi or Tunis—let alone in Moscow where it is considered unthinkable to ask.  


But, unfashionable as it may be, it is a very real question.  


The Western institutions are not mechanical formulae.

They are the fruit of long, painful development.

They are not interchangeable machine parts that will fit any standard model, but living tissue in an organic body of values and experience, emotions and history, martyrs and precepts.  


The Speaker of Parliament, in some newly organized government of a newly independent country on the West Coast of Africa, sports the wig and the mace of the Speaker at Westminster.

He follows the procedures of the “Mother of Parliaments” with pomp, punctilio and relish.

The spiritual ancestry of the Right Honorable Gentleman who sits in the Speaker’s chair in Nigeria or at the Gold Coast includes all the political thinkers, statesmen and parliamentarians of the English tradition, back to the Barons at Runnymede.

It extends beyond them into the dim antiquity of Greece and Rome.  


Yet his father after the flesh was a tribal chieftain or a witch doctor, and his own roots are in a tribal society living in the Bronze Age.

He may repudiate his physical father.

But he cannot repudiate the society whence he came.

This tribal Bronze Age society is his constituency.

He can only be effective if he can convey to it what he stands for, if he can move it to follow where he leads.  


In the entire country, with all the elaborate system of parliament, responsible ministers, law courts, civil servants and so forth, there may be only three hundred people with enough education and enough knowledge of the traditions of the West to understand what all these institutions are about, let alone how to run them.

What will happen when these men are gone?

Will they be able to bring up successors fast enough?

Will there be enough time for these transplanted institutions to take root, and enough loving care and understanding to make them grow and prosper?

How will they be integrated with a tribal community—can they be integrated at all?

Will these Western institutions become means to unify the new nation?

Or will they aggravate traditional hostilities and cleavages?

Will they, in other words, become mere slogans to justify tyranny and terror, bloodshed and civil war, exploitation and paralysis, cruelty and lawlessness?  


These questions must be asked not only of Tunisia or the Gold Coast but also of India—and even more of China.

The number of people in India with knowledge and understanding of Western values and institutions, and with real personal commitment to them, may not be so much larger proportionately than it is in West Africa.

There is the same doubt that Communism can remain viable in a non-Western country like China, after the passing of the first Western-trained generation; but for us, in the Free World, this is cold comfort.  


The speed and ease with which Western technology—industrial and military—is spreading throughout the non-Western world only adds to the seriousness of the situation.

Technology is not a disembodied abstraction or a mere tool; it grows out of cultural and historical traditions and demands cultural and social foundations.

Because of this, it cannot simply be imposed on an existing culture.

Any culture that does not conform to the exacting demands of technology—whether African tribe, Indian caste or Chinese family—will be ruthlessly destroyed.

But can technology, however productive of a higher standard of living or of a higher standard of warfare and dying, produce a culture and a community?  


Technology in the West grew out of our own cultural foundations.

The roots of the great technological changes of the last two hundred years go back all the way to the surge of the Middle Ages (the great cathedrals too were an “industrial revolution”) and even further back to the Rule of St. Benedict.

We have had a long time to get used to this “new growth,” so that we could develop “antibodies.”

In the nonWestern world, however, modern technology is a “foreign body.”

Its growth is explosive and much too fast to make possible the development of really effective antibodies.  


This may make easier the adaptation of the non-Western world to Western political and social institutions by destroying those political and social traditions that stand in their way.

It may force more thorough commitment to the basic values that underlie these institutions.

But it may also uproot and weaken these non-Western countries before they can grow into cohesive societies.

---***---

In the disappearance of the East and in its Westernization the great themes of the post-modern world all come together.  


Education is the cause of Westernization; but the educated society is also the great need of the new world, the shortage of educated people is its great lack, and the development of an effective model of general education its great hope.  


The vision of economic development is the driving force behind Westernization.

The force that, in twenty years, made trucks rather than the backs of coolies up-to-date transportation in Bangkok also changes expectations, beliefs and ways of life unchanged since time immemorial.

At the same time the new danger of interracial and international class war resulting from the failure of economic development is the great threat both to the old West and the new Westernizing countries.  


These countries have no choice but to imitate the political institutions of modern government; they have to become nation-states.

They can only survive if their political institutions become effective.

Yet these institutions are just as inadequate there for the tasks of international affairs as they are in the West, and just as endangered there by the cancerous growth of military technology and the resulting militarization of society.  


Above all these countries need the new, post-modern, post-Cartesian world-view.

This alone can enable them to integrate the best of their own non-Western tradition with the beliefs, the institutions, the knowledge, the tools of the West.

And no living civilization can clothe itself entirely in somebody else’s cast-off garments.  


The emergence of a common, basically Western world civilization is the greatest of our new frontiers—the greatest change and the greatest opportunity.

But in whose image will it be cast? ↓

 

Post-Capitalist Society

 

Luther, Machiavelli, and the Salmon

 

The MEMO they don’t want you to SEE



Keywords: tlnkwdruckerbook

 

“The greatest danger in times of turbulence is not turbulence;

it is to act with yesterday’s logic”. — Peter Drucker

 

 

The shift from manual workers
who do as they are being told
either by the task or by the boss —

TO knowledge workers
who have to manage themselves

profoundly challenges social structure

 

Managing Oneself (PDF) is a REVOLUTION in human affairs.” …

“It also requires an almost 180-degree change in the knowledge workers’ thoughts and actions from what most of us—even of the younger generation—still take for granted as the way to think and the way to act.” …

… “Managing Oneself is based on the very opposite realities:
Workers are likely to outlive organizations (and therefore, employers can’t be depended on for designing your life),

and the knowledge worker has mobility.” ← in a context

 

 

More than anything else,

the individual
has to take more responsibility
for himself or herself,
rather than depend on the company.”
continue

 

“Making a living is no longer enough
‘Work’ has to make a life .” continue

finding and selecting the pieces of the puzzle

 

The Second Curve

 

line

 

These pages are attention directing tools for navigating a world moving relentlessly toward unimagined futures.

 

evidence-wall-and-time-line-pict-600

What’s the next effective action on the road ahead

 

stages-simple-horizons-pict-t

 

It’s up to you to figure out what to harvest and calendarize
working something out in time (1915, 1940, 1970 … 2040 … the outer limit of your concern)nobody is going to do it for you.

It may be a step forward to actively reject something (rather than just passively ignoring) and then working out a plan for coping with what you’ve rejected.

Your future is between your ears and our future is between our collective ears — it can’t be otherwise.

A site exploration: The memo THEY don't want you to see

 

Google

To create a rlaexp.com site search, go to Google’s site ↓

Type the following in their search box ↓

your search text site:rlaexp.com

intelligence-instructions

 

What needs doing?

 

contact

 



Copyright 1985 through 2024 © All rights reserved | bobembry bobembryusa bobembry.usa | bob embry robert embry | “time life navigation” © #TimeLifeNavigation | “life TIME investment system” © #LifeTimeInvestmentSystem | “career evolution” © #CareerEvolution | “work-life horizons” © | “work-life evolution” © | “life design” © #LifeDesign | “organization evolution” © | #OrganizationEvolution | “brainroads toward tomorrows” © | #BrainroadsTowardTomorrows | “foundations for future directed decisions” © | #FoundationsForFutureDirectedDecisions | #rlaexpdotcom © | rlaexpdotcom ©

#rlaexp.com = rla + exp = real life adventures + exploration or explored

exploration leads to explored

Examples ↑ can be found through web searches, Wikipedia,
Pinterest and the daily news

 

As an Amazon Associate I earn from qualifying purchases